On The Revelation Of Private Information In The U.S. Crop Insurance Program

27.12.2007 716 views
On The Revelation Of Private Information In The U.S. Crop Insurance Program

Ergun, A Tolga; Ker, Alan

The crop insurance program is a prominent facet of U.S. farm policy. The participation of private insurance companies as intermediaries is justified on the basis of efficiency gains. These gains may arise from either decreased transaction costs through better established delivery channels and/or the revelation of private information. We find empirical evidence suggesting that private information is revealed by insurance companies via their reinsurance decisions. However, it is unlikely that such information will be incorporated into subsequent premium rates by the government.

 

The crop insurance program is a prominent facet of U.S. farm policy. The participation of private insurance companies as intermediaries is justified on the basis of efficiency gains. These gains may arise from either decreased transaction costs through better established delivery channels and/or the revelation of private information. We find empirical evidence suggesting that private information is revealed by insurance companies via their reinsurance decisions. However, it is unlikely that such information will be incorporated into subsequent premium rates by the government.INTRODUCTIONFederally regulated crop insurance programs have been a prominent part of U.S. agricultural policy since the 1930s. In 2004, the estimated number of crop insurance policies exceeded 1.24 million with total liabilities exceeding $45 billion. Traditional crop insurance schemes offer farmers the opportunity to insure against yield losses resulting from nearly all risks, including such things as drought, fire, flood, hail, and pests. A variety of crop insurance plans and a number of new pilot programs are currently under development. In the crop insurance program three economic interests are served: the federal government through the United States Department of Agriculture's Risk Management Agency (RMA), the producers or farmers, and the private insurance companies. In 1980, insurance companies were solicited by the federal government to increase farmer participation. Intermediaries are often used in public policy if efficiency gains are expected. In the crop insurance program, efficiency gains could be expected through two avenues. First, the better established delivery channels of insurance companies could reach a greater number of producers at a given cost. Second, the exploitation of private information (if it exists with the insurance companies) can increase the accuracy of premium rates, thereby decreasing adverse selection losses.1 In this article, we empirically test if insurance companies reveal private information about risk profiles to the RMA via their reinsurance decisions. Not only is this of economic interest, it is a timely empirical question given the sizeable public funds needed to operate the crop insurance program and that a significant share of those funds-rivaling that of producers-resides with the insurance companies (see Figure 1).We use semiparametric as well as parametric methods to determine whether a set of policies returns a profit or not using a data set aggregated to the crop-county-year combination. We consider models with and without explanatory variables depicting the allocation decisions of insurance companies. The use of semiparametric methods, which avoid strong distributional assumptions, proves useful as we reject the parametric method.The remainder of the article proceeds as follows. The second section "Insurance Companies and the Standard Reinsurance Agreement" provides a terse review of the involvement of insurance companies in the U.S. crop insurance program. The third section "Data and Methodology" discusses the data and outlines the econometric methods. The fourth section "Estimation Results" presents the results, while the final section focuses on the corresponding policy implications.INSURANCE COMPANIES AND THE STANDARD REINSURANCE AGREEMENTThere is a surprisingly small literature on the role of insurance companies in the U.S. crop insurance program (see Miranda and Glauber, 1997; Ker, 2001). Figure 1 illustrates the breakdown of government program outlays into producer subsidies, indemnities less premiums, administrative and operating reimbursement for insurance companies, and underwriting gains/losses accrued by insurance companies.2 There are a number of interesting features: (1) producer subsidies increased dramatically in 1995 (a result of the 1994 Federal Crop Insurance Act) and again in 2001 (a result of the 2000 Agricultural Risk Protection Act (ARPA)), (2) indemnities less premiums are quite volatile, (3) insurance companies' administrative and operating expenses have risen with increases in total premiums, and (4) underwriting gains accruing to insurance companies have increased dramatically since 1994. Given the significant underwriting gains realized by insurance companies, it is of economic interest to determine if they reveal private information through their reinsurance decisions.The involvement of insurance companies in the U.S. crop insurance program is defined by the Standard Reinsurance Agreement (SRA). Insurance companies sell policies and conduct claim adjustments. In return/the RMA compensates them for the corresponding aclrninistrative and operating expenses. The underwriting gains/losses are shared asymmetrically, between the insurance companies and the RMA. Both the provisions by which the underwriting gains and losses are shared and the reimbursement for administrative and operating expenses are set out in the SRA.Section II.A.2 of the 2005 SRA states that an insurance company ". . . must offer and market all plans of insurance for all crops in any State where actuarial documents are available in which it writes an eligible crop insurance contract and must accept and approve all applications from all eligible producers." An eligible farmer will not be denied access to an available, federally subsidized, crop insurance product. Therefore, an insurance company conducting business in a state cannot discriminate among farmers, crops, or insurance products in that state. This is unusual in that the responsibility for pricing the crop policies lies with the RMA but the insurance companies must accept some liability for each policy they write and cannot choose which policy they will or will not write.Two mechanisms are provided to entice insurance companies to participate. First, given that insurance companies do not set premium rates, there is a mechanism in the SRA by which they can cede the majority of the liability of an undesirable policy. In a private market, the insurance company would not write a policy deemed undesirable. second, given that RMA premium rates do not reflect a return to the insurance company's capital, the SRA provides asymmetric sharing of underwriting gains/losses. Essentially, the SRA provides two mechanisms that emulate a private market from the perspective of the insurance company. In so doing, it also provides a vehicle by which an insurance company uses its information regarding farmer risk profiles to transfer unwanted policies to the RMA.The first parameter, ^sup k^^sub 1^, is fixed at 0.2 for the assigned risk fund but represents an ex ante choice variable for the insurance company with respect to the commercial and developmental funds. For the development fund ^sup k^^sub 1^ [0.35,1.0], while for the commercial fund ^sup k^^sub 1^ [0.5,1.0]. The insurance company must choose ^sup k^^sub 1^ by July 1 of the preceding crop year.The second parameter, ^sup k^^sub 2^, is not a fixed scalar, but a function of the fund loss ratio. Figure 2 illustrates the relationship between the fund loss ratio and the percentage of premiums retained by the insurance company. For example, if the percentage of premiums retained is -20 percent and the total premiums were $1 million, the insurance company would incur a loss of $200,000. The fund loss ratio is defined as the ratio of total indemnities to total premiums.Note the differences between the percentage of premiums retained for each of the three funds. Consider, for example, if the assigned risk fund has $2 million in premiums and $3 million in indemnities. The loss ratio would be 1.5 and the underwriting loss would be $1 million. For the assigned risk fund, the insurance company would be liable for 0.92 percent or only $9,200 of the $1 million underwriting loss. Given total premiums of $2 million the percentage of premiums retained by the insurance company would be only -0.46 percent. If, on the other hand, this underwriting loss occurred in the commercial fund with ^sub 1^ = 1, the insurance company would be liable for 46 percent or $460,000 of the $1 rnillion underwriting loss, resulting in a percentage of premiums retained of -23 percent. Consider a second example: if premiums were $2 million and indemnities were only $1 million, the loss ratio would be 0.5 and the underwriting gain would be $1 million. For the assigned risk fund, the insurance company would retain 2.64 percent ($26,400) of the underwriting gain and, as such, the percentage of premiums retained would be 1.32 percent. If, on the other hand, this underwriting gain occurred in the commercial fund with ^sub 1^ = 1, the insurance company would retain 86.8 percent ($868,000) of the underwriting gain and, as such, the percentage of premiums retained would be 43.4 percent.

 It is apparent from these examples that policies that a profit-maximizing insurance company expects to be profitable would be placed in the commercial fund where they share a high percentage of any underwriting gains and losses. Conversely, policies that a profit-maximizing insurance company expects to be unprofitable would be placed in the assigned risk fund where they share a low percentage of any underwriting gains and losses.The expected profit-maximizing optimal reinsurance of policies across the three funds is extremely complicated. Given that there exist three possible funds for which any policy may be allocated, and, assuming N policies, there are 3^sup N^ possible reinsurance allocations. For example, if N = 500 there exist 3.636E + 238 possible reinsurance allocations, all of which need to be evaluated in terms of expected profit. Not only is it untenable for the insurance company to undertake this, but to do so requires an estimate of the joint density of yields for the N policies-impossible, given the scarce data.3 Fortunately, our empirical analysis only requires that insurance companies allocate policies that they expect to be relatively more profitable to the commercial fund as opposed to the assigned risk fund. It is apparent from the above examples that this requirement is consistent with profit-maximizing behavior.Two final points regarding the SRA require discussion. First, there exist separate developmental and commercial funds for "catastrophic policies," "revenue policies," and "other policies" that comprise multiple peril crop insurance policies and Group Risk Plan policies (Group Risk Plan policies make up a negligible fraction of the total policies). We focus our attention on the three fund allocations for the "other policies" because insurance companies have significantly less experience and historical information with the "revenue policies" and "catastrophic policies" and thus their reinsurance decisions may not be as efficient. Also note, that while these funds (except assigned risk) are not aggregated across types of policies, they are aggregated across crops. second, insurance companies face a constraint, at the state level, on the maximum percentage of premiums in their book of business that can be placed in the assigned risk fund. These maximums vary quite significantly by state. While this may inhibit the insurance companies' ability to cede unwanted policies, by choosing fxi = 0.35 for the developmental fund they can make it resemble the assigned risk fund (see Figure 2) and there are no such percentages of premium restrictions for the development fund.DATA AND METHODOLOGYRecall that we wish to test whether relevant private information is revealed in the reinsurance decisions of insurance companies. This hypothesis can be tested by predicting whether policies are profitable or not using two models. The first model uses public information as explanatory variables. The second model nests the first and includes the additional variables representing the reinsurance decisions of the insurance companies. Specifically, we test whether the percentage of correct predictions increases significantly with the inclusion of these reinsurance variables.The data comprise the premiums, indemnities, liability, and number of policies in each of the three funds by crop-county-year combination. We have data on corn, cotton, soybeans, and wheat for the reinsurance years 1998,1999,2000, and 2001. We remove combinations with less than $500,000 in liability leaving 7,602 crop-countyyear combinations.Two caveats regarding our data need noting. First, our data are aggregated to the county level; we do not have policy-specific reinsurance decisions. second, our data are aggregated across insurance companies. While we would prefer policy and company-specific reinsurance decisions and requested such, we were only able to obtain aggregated data from RMA. This lack of precision will reduce the power of our tests.The explanatory variables used in our analysis are crop dummies for cotton, soybeans, and wheat, historical loss ratio, ratio of current liability to the previous year liability (denoted liability ratio), the maximum percentage of premiums allowed in the assigned risk fund for that state (denoted state risk), percentage of premiums placed in the commercial fund, and the percentage of premiums placed in the assigned risk fund.5 We do not include the percentage of premiums placed in the developmental fund since that would result in a singularity problem as the sum of the three percentages in the three funds equals one for each crop-county combination.Econometric MethodologyOptimization-based estimation methods have been developed for single-index models without making distributional assumptions and thus avoiding misspecification. These include Ichimura (1993) and Klein and Spady (1993). The first of these estimators is based on minimizing a nonlinear least squares loss function and the latter is based on maximizing a profile likelihood function. The latter estimator is developed specifically for binary-choice model estimation. Ichimura and Klein and Spady show yfh convergence and asymptotic normality of their estimators and give a consistent covariance estimator. Since the estimators (and results) are almost identical we only present the results from the Ichimura estimator.Note that we need a location-scale normalization for identification purposes in singleindex models. Since the link function F is assumed to be completely unknown, the intercept term cannot be identified as is subsumed in the definition of F. Also, a scale normalization is needed for the same reason that it is imposed in parametric models (assuming the error term has unit variance). This scale normalization in the semiparametric models can be achieved by setting the coefficient of one continuous regressor equal to a constant.7In single-index models, the asymptotic distribution of the normalized and centered estimator does not depend on the smoothing parameter, so asymptotically, any sequence of smoothing parameters is going to give the same estimate as long as it satisfies certain conditions.9 For this reason, in semiparametric single-index models, selection of the smoothing parameter has not been well studied. One exception is Hardle, Hall, and Ichimura (1993) who show the SLS estimator of Ichimura (1993) can be expanded as A(b) + B(h) and can be minimized simultaneously with respect to both b and h. This is like separately minimizing A(b) with respect to b and B(h) with respect to h. The end result is a [the square root of]n-consistent estimator of b and an asymptotically optimal estimator of h, in the sense that h/ho -+ 1 as n -? oo where ho is the optimal bandwidth for estimating F when b is known and is proportional to n-1/5 as usual in nonparametrics (see Hardle, Hall, and Ichimura 1993, for technical details). We apply this idea to the SLS objective function and hence we optimize with respect to both b and h. To our knowledge, this is the first article that uses this idea in practice other than the original Handle, Hall, and Ichimura (1993) article. Note that in estimating F, we are excluding observation i so that we are "cross-validating" the objective functions. In the estimations we use a normal density function truncated at plus and minus three standard deviations as the kernel.ESTIMATION RESULTSTo test our hypothesis, we randomly partition our sample into an estimation sample (3,801 observations) and a prediction sample (3,801 observations). We evaluate our hypothesis using out-of-sample methods rather than within-sample methods because insurance companies must make reinsurance decisions out-of-sample and out-ofsample tests minimize spurious results from over-fitting the data (particularly for semiparametric methods which, if applied inappropriately, can be made to over-fit the data). We also conducted three tests for the appropriateness of the probit model and all rejected it (see the Appendix for details and test results).The estimation results and predictive performances for the models without and with the reinsurance variables are located in Table 1 (standard errors are in parentheses). For the semiparametric estimator we restrict the intercept to 0 and the parameter estimate on the historical loss ratio to the probit estimate as is commonly done.10We have no expectations about the signs of the crop dummy variables although we do have expectations about the signs of the other parameter estimates. First, the sign of liability ratio is negative as expected. If liability increases (decreases) significantly from one year to the next, this may suggest that producers perceive their return to that insurance policy to have increased (decreased), and thus the expected return for the insurance company may decrease (increase). The parameter estimate on state risk is negative (as expected) and significant. This indicates, quite interestingly, that policies in those states with higher bounds on the percentage of premiums allowed in the assigned risk fund are less likely to be profitable. The parameter estimates on the historical loss ratio in the probit models are negative and significant as expected; the higher the loss ratio, the less likely the policies are profitable. The parameter on the percentage of premiums in the commercial fund is positive as expected. This suggests that policies the insurance company places in the commercial fund are more likely to be profitable. This is statistically significant in both the probit and semiparametric models. Finally, the parameter on the assigned variable is negative as expected suggesting that policies the insurance company places in the assigned risk fund are less likely to be profitable.

 The out-of-sample tests show that predictive performance increases significantly when the reinsurance variables are included, indicating that there exists relevant private information revealed through the allocation decisions of the insurance companies.12 This coincides with the in-sample results that suggested that the explanatory variables depicting the reinsurance decisions were significant in explaining profitable and nonprofitable sets of policies. Therefore, we reject the null that no relevant private information is revealed in the reinsurance data.CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONSAlthough the crop insurance program has garnered significant attention in the academic literature, surprisingly little has focused on the involvement of insurance companies. However, the public rents obtained by the insurance companies in return for their involvement are close to rivaling those obtained by producers (see Figure 1). Consequently, more research is needed, both theoretically and empirically, focusing on the involvement of insurance companies as intermediaries.This article considered whether insurance companies reveal private information through their reinsurance decisions. We conducted out-of-sample tests and showed that the insurance companies do possess statistically significant private information that may warrant their involvement in the crop insurance program in addition to program delivery efficiencies. Although RMA can adjust their rates over time, they face many political and legal constraints in doing so. Therefore, it is unknown whether RMA could in fact adjust their rates to reflect the revelation of private information. A review of the rating methodologies for all RMA insurance products reveals that the reinsurance behavior of insurance companies is not currently part of any RMA rate-setting formulas.The policy implications of our results do not call into question the use of insurance companies as intermediaries in the U.S. crop insurance program. The reality is that the program is simply too large to operate without private insurance companies. The results may call into question whether RMA should share the underwriting gains/losses with insurance companies.13 If risk sharing were eliminated, the administrative and operating expense reimbursement may need to be increased to maintain the participation of insurance companies that do so with the expectation of realizing underwriting gains. Removal of these without compensation could dramatically alter the level of insurance company involvement and hence the delivery of the program. Certainly, there is much room for future research on the role of insurance companies in the U.S. crop insurance program. FOOTNOTE1 Although the revelation of private information is of economic interest, this rationale was not considered by legislators in any deliberations leading to the passage of the Federal Crop Insurance Act of 1980; the Act that established private sector delivery.2 Underwriting gains/losses are defined as total premiums less total indemnities. However, because insurance companies and the government share the underwriting gains /losses asymmetrically by state and certain insurance programs, it is possible that the insurance program as a whole experiences an underwriting loss while the insurance companies experience em underwriting gain. Similarly, the reverse is also possible.3 The reader is directed to Ker and McGowan (2000) for a detailed investigation of a profit-maximizing insurance company's optimal allocation strategy of policies across the three types of funds.4 Our dependent variable is based on whether a set of policies returned a profit or not rather than the level of profit. Consider the reinsurance decision of the insurance company. Whether a policy is expected to be marginally or significantly above a specific profit level, it is reinsured with the commercial fund. All that RMA can ascertain about a policy that has been allocated to the commercial fund is that expected profit is above a specific and unknown level. Therefore, our dependent variable is restricted to whether a set of policies returned a profit or not. However, we did repeat the analysis using the loss ratio and the results remained unchanged. FOOTNOTE5 The historical loss ratio is calculated using data from 1981 to the year prior to the crop year. That is, the historical loss ratio for policies in crop year 1999 comprises data from 1981 to 1998.6 See the maximum score estimator of Manski (1975) and its smoothed version by Horowitz (1992) for estimators that can accommodate arbitrary forms of heteroskedasticity although at the cost of a rate of convergence slower than [the square root of]n. FOOTNOTE7 An alternative scale normalization would be 11 = 1 where ois the Euclidean norm.8 Note that in these semiparametric estimators, asymptotic theory requires trimming those observations for which the index is arbitrarily close to the boundary of its support. For the Ichimura estimator, knowledge of the distribution of the index is required, which is unknown in practice. Other applied papers (Horowitz, 1993; Gerfin, 19%; Fernandez and RodriguezPoo, 1997) do not consider trimming. As Horowitz (1993, p. 53) explains "This amounts to assuming that the support of [index] is larger than that observed in the data."9 But in finite samples the performance of the estimators can be very sensitive to the choice of this smoothing parameter.10 This parameter can be set to any finite constant.11 RMA faces legal and political constraints in setting rates and subsequently they do not reflect all public information. We were unable to obtain unconstrained or target rates from RMA in hopes of including the ratio of constrained to unconstrained rates as an explanatory variable in our regressions. However, the target rates are generally derived from the historical loss ratio that is included in our analyses. Therefore, we are jointly testing the significance of private information and the residual rate-setting constraints not captured by the historical loss ratio variable.12 A LR test confirms this result for the probit models. FOOTNOTE13 The only economic rationale would be to ensure that the government and insurance companies are incentive compatible with respect to fraud. However, given the existence of the assigned risk and developmental funds that enable insurance companies to cede the vast majority of the liability of unwanted policies, this goal is not necessarily attainable under the current SRA.14 As the number of regressors increases, estimation precision declines rapidly. This phenomenon is known as the curse of dimensionality.15 Härdle, Mammen, Proença (2000) suggest using bootstrap methods instead of a normal approximation to calculate critical values and show that bootstrap yields better approximations to the critical values in a simulation study with n = 200. We, however, feel more comfortable using normal approximation as we have a relatively large sample (n = 3,801).The second test calculates the difference in the predictive performance of the semiparametric method versus the probit for the two models. For models without reinsurance variables, the difference in the percentage correctly predicted is 3.18 percent with a standard error of 0.557 percent. For models with the reinsurance variables, the difference in the percentage correctly predicted is 4.39 percent percent with a standard error of 0.504 percent. Standard errors are calculated by bootstrapping the prediction sample and recovering the difference in the percentage of correct predictions (500 bootstraps are used). These test results strongly reject the probit model in favor of the semiparametric method.A third test follows the graphical approach of Horowitz (1998, p. 53). Figures Al and A2 show the nonparametric kernel estimates of d F /dz, pointwise 95 percent bootstrap confidence interval, and the normal density function. Note that for a probit model, dF/dz would be the normal density function. In these nonparametric estimations, we used the standard normal density as our kernel. For bandwidth selection, we initially tried cross-validation for derivative estimation (see Härdle, 1990, pp. 160-161). Numerical minimization of this objective function was not successful for the most part so after experimenting with cross validation, we chose the bandwidths accordingly. The derivative of the link functions is clearly left skewed and hence cannot be accommodated by the symmetric normal density. Pointwise confidence intervals are represented by the dotted lines. The derivatives are bimodal, which suggests that the true data-generating processes may possibly be a mixture of two populations. Using a parametric probit model clearly misses these features of the data. ReferencesFernandez, A. I., and J. M. Rodriguez-Poo, 1997, Estimation and Specification Testing in Female Labor Participation Models: Parametric and Semiparametric Methods, Econometric Reviews, 16:229-247.Gerfin, M., 1996, Parametric and Semiparametric Estimation of the Binary Response Model of Labour Market Participation, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11:321-339.Hardle, W., 1990, Applied Nonparametric Regression (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press).Härdle, W., P. Hall, and H. Ichimura, 1993, Optimal Smoothing in Single-Index Models, The Annals of Statistics, 21:157-178.

25.10.2022

A Practical Method for Adjusting the Premium Rates in Crop-Hail Insurance with Short-Term Insurance Data

The frequency of hailstorms is generally low in small geographic areas. In other words, it may be very likely that hailstorm occurrences will vary between neighboring locations within a short period of time. Besides, a newly launched insurance scheme lacks the data. It is, therefore, difficult to sustain a sound insurance program under these circumstances, with premium rates based on meteorological data without a complimentary adjustment process.

18.10.2019

Malta - Vegetable production dropped 7% in 2018

Last year, Malta’s local vegetable produce dropped by 7% when compared to the previous year. The total vegetables produced in tonnes amounted to 58,178, down by 7% when compared to 2017. Their value too diminished as the total produce was valued at €30 million, down by 13% over the previous year. The most significant drop was in potatoes, down by 27% over the previous year. Tomatoes and onions were the only vegetables to have increased in volume, by 3% and 4% respectively but their value diminished by 9% and 24% respectively. The figures were published by the National Statistics Office on the event of World Food Day 2019, which will be celebrated on Wednesday. Cauliflower, cabbage and lettuce produce dropped by 10%, 3%, and 12% respectively. In the realm of local fruit, a drop of produce was registered here too apart from strawberries, which experienced a whopping increase of 58% over 2017. Total fruit produced in 2018 amounted to 13,057 tonnes, down by 1% when compared to 2017. The total produce was valued at €10 million, a 3% increase in value. Peaches produced were down by 35% and the 376 tonnes of peaches cultivated amounted to €0.5 million in value. Orange produce dropped by 10% and lemon produce dropped by 14%. There was no change in the amount of grapes produced and the 3,642 tonnes of grapes produced in 2018 were valued at €2.3 million. 70% of fruit and vegetables consumed in Malta is imported. The drop in local produce could be the result of deleterious or unsuitable weather patterns. Source - https://www.freshplaza.com

07.10.2019

USA - Greenhouse tomato production spans most states

While Florida and California accounted for 76 percent of U.S. production of field-grown tomatoes in 2016, greenhouse production and use of other protected-culture technologies help extend the growing season and make production feasible in a wider variety of geographic locations. Some greenhouse production is clustered in traditional field-grown-tomato-producing States like California. However, high concentrations of greenhouses are also located in Nebraska, Minnesota, New York, and other States that are not traditional market leaders. Among the benefits that greenhouse tomato producers can realize are greater market access both in the off-season and in northern retail produce markets, better product consistency, and improved yields. These benefits make greenhouse tomato production an increasingly attractive alternative to field production despite higher production costs. In addition to domestic production, a significant share of U.S. consumption of greenhouse tomatoes is satisfied by imports. In 2004, U.S., Mexican, and Canadian growers each contributed about 300 million pounds of greenhouse tomatoes annually to the U.S. fresh tomato market. Since then, Mexico’s share of the greenhouse tomato market has grown sharply, accounting for almost 84 percent (1.8 billion pounds) of the greenhouse volume coming into the U.S. market. Source - https://www.freshplaza.com

03.10.2019

World cherry production will decrease to 3.6 million tons

According to information from the USDA for the 2019-2020 season, world cherry production is expected to decrease slightly and amount to 3.6 million tons. This decline is due to the damages that the weather caused on cherry crops in the European Union. Even though Chile is expected to achieve a record export, world trade in cherries is expected to drop to 454,000 tons, based on lower shipments from Uzbekistan and the US. Turkey Turkey's production is expected to increase to 865,000. As a result of the strong export demand, producers continue to invest and improve their orchards, switching to high yield varieties and gradually expanding the surface for sweet cherries. More supplies are expected to increase exports to a record 78,000 tons, continuing its long upward trend. Chile Chile's production is forecast to increase from 30,000 tons to 231,000 as they have a larger area of mature trees. Between 2009/10 and 2018/19, the crop area has almost tripled, a trend that is expected to continue. The country is expected to export up to 205,000 tons in higher supplies. The percentage of exports destined for China has increased from 13 to almost 90% since 2009/10. China China's production is expected to increase by up to 24% and to amount to 420,000 tons, due to the recovery of the orchards that were damaged by frost last year. In addition, there are new crops that will go into production. Imports are expected to increase by 15,000 tons and to stand at 195,000 tons, as the increase in supplies from Chile will more than compensate for the lower shipments from the United States. Although higher tariffs are maintained for American cherries, the United States is expected to remain China's main supplier in the northern hemisphere. United States US production is expected to remain stable at 450,000 tons. Imports are expected to increase to 18,000 tons with more supplies available from Chile. Exports are forecast to decrease for the second consecutive year to 80,000 tons, as high retaliatory tariffs continue to suppress US shipments to China. If this happens, it will be the first time that US cherry exports experience a decrease in 2 consecutive years since 2002/03, when production suffered a fall of 44%. European Union EU production is projected to fall by more than 20%, remaining at 648,000 tons because of the hail that affected the early varieties in Italy, and the frost, low temperatures, and drought that caused a significant loss of fruit in Poland, the main producer. Lower supplies are expected to pressure exports to 15,000 tons and increase imports to 55,000 tons. Russia Russia's imports are expected to contract by 13,000 tons to 80,000 with lower supplies from Kazakhstan, Moldova, and Serbia. Source - https://www.freshplaza.com

09.08.2019

EU - 20% fewer apples and 14% fewer pears than last year

This year's European apple production is expected to come to 10,556,000 tons. That is 20% less than last year. It is also 8% less than the average over the past three years. The European pear harvest is expected to be 2,047,000 tons. This is 14% lower than last year and 9% less than the previous three seasons average. These figures are according to the World Apple and Pear Association, WAPA's top fruit prognoses. They presented their report at Prognosfruit this morning. Apple harvest per country Poland is Europe's apple-growing giant. This country is expected to process 44% fewer apples. The yield is expected to be 2,710,000 tons. Last year, this was still 4,810,000 tons. In Italy, yields are only three percent lower than last year. According to WAPA, this country will have an apple harvest of 2,195,000 tons. France takes third place. They will even have 12% more apples than last year to process - 1,652,000 tons. Pear harvest per country With 511,000 tons, Italy's pear harvest is much lower than last year. It has dropped by 30%. In terms of the average over the previous three seasons, this fruit's yield is 29% lower. In the Netherlands, the pear harvest is expected to be six percent lower, at 379,000 tons. This volume is still 3% more than the average over the last three years. Belgium has 10% fewer pears (331,000 tons) than last year. They are just ahead of Spain. With 311,000 tons, Spain who will harvest four percent more pears. Apple harvest per variety The Golden Delicious remains, by far, the largest apple variety in Europe. It is expected that 2,327,000 tons of these apples will be harvested this year. This is three percent less than last year. At 1,467,000 tons, Gala estimations are exactly the same as last year. The European Elstar harvest will also be roughly equivalent to last year. A volume of 355,000 tons of this variety is expected. Pear harvest per variety Looking at the different varieties, the European Conference is estimated to be 8% lower than last year. A volume of 910,000 tons is expected. The low Italian pear estimate will result in 34% fewer Abate Fetel pears (211,000 tons) being available. This is according to WAPA's estimate. This makes this variety smaller than the Williams BC (230.000 ton) in Europe. Source - https://www.freshplaza.com

30.01.2018

Spring frost losses and climate change not a contradiction in terms - Munich Re

Between 17 April and 10 May 2017, large parts of Europe were hit by a cold snap that brought a series of overnight frosts. As the budding process was already well advanced due to an exceptionally warm spring, losses reached historic levels – particularly for fruit and wine growers: economic losses are estimated at €3.3bn, with around €600m of this insured. In the second and third ten-day periods of April, and in some cases even over the first ten days of May 2017, western, central, southern and eastern Europe experienced a series of frosty nights, with catastrophic consequences in many places for fruit growing and viticulture. The worst-affected countries were Italy, France, Germany, Poland, Spain and Switzerland. Losses were so high because vegetation was already well advanced following an exceptionally warm spell of weather in March that continued into the early part of April. For example, the average date of apple flowering in 2017 for Germany as a whole was 20 April, seven days earlier than the average for the period 1992 to 2016. In many parts of Germany, including the Lake Constance fruit-growing region, it even began before 15 April. In the case of cherry trees – whose average flowering date in Germany in 2017 was 6 April – it was as much as twelve days earlier than the long-term average. The frost had a devastating impact because of the early start of the growing season in many parts of Europe. In the second half of April, it affected the sensitive blossoms, the initial fruiting stages and the first frost-susceptible shoots on vines. Meteorological conditions The weather conditions that accounted for the frosty nights are a typical feature of April, and also the reason for the month’s proverbial reputation for changeable weather. The corridor of fast-moving upper air flow, also known as the polar front, forms in such a way that it moves in over central Europe from northwesterly directions near Iceland. This north or northwest pattern frequently occurs if there is high air pressure over the eastern part of the North Atlantic, and lower air pressure over the Baltic and the northwest of Russia. Repeated low-pressure areas move along this corridor towards Europe, bringing moist and cold air masses behind their cold fronts from the areas of Greenland and Iceland. Occasionally, the high-pressure area can extend far over the continent in an easterly direction. The flow then brings dry, cold air to central Europe from high continental latitudes moving in a clockwise direction around the high. It was precisely this set of weather conditions with its higher probability of overnight frost that dominated from mid-April to the end of the month. There were frosts with temperatures falling below –5°C, in particular from 17 to 24 April (second and third ten-day periods of April), and even into the first ten-day period of May in eastern Europe. The map in Fig. 2 shows the areas that experienced night-time temperatures of –2°C and below in April/May. High losses in fruit and wine growing Frost damage to plants comes from intracellular ice formation. The cell walls collapse and the plant mass then dries out. The loss pattern is therefore similar to what is seen after a drought. Agricultural crops are at varying risk from frost in the different phases of growth. They are especially sensitive during flowering and shortly after budding, as was the case with fruit and vines in April 2017 due to the early onset of the growing season. That was why the losses were so exceptionally high in this instance. In Spain, the cold snap also affected cereals, which were already flowering by this date. Even risk experts were surprised at the geographic extent and scale of the losses (overall losses: €3.3bn, insured losses: approximately €600m). Overall losses were highest in Italy and France, with figures of approximately a billion euros recorded in each country. Two basic concepts for frost insurance As frost has always been considered a destructive natural peril for fruit and wine growing and horticulture, preventive measures are widespread. In horticulture, for example, plants are cultivated in greenhouses or under covers, while in fruit growing, frost-protection measures include the use of sprinkler irrigation as well as wind machines or helicopters to mix the air layers. Just how effective these methods prove to be will depend on meteorological conditions, which is precisely why risk transfer is so important in this sector. There are significant differences between one country and the next in terms of insurability and insurance solutions. But essentially there are two basic concepts available for frost insurance: indemnity insurance, where hail cover is extended to include frost or other perils yield guarantee insurance covering all natural perils In most countries, the government subsidises insurance premiums, which means that insurance penetration is higher. In Germany, where premiums are not subsidised and frost insurance density is low, individual federal states like Bavaria and Baden-Württemberg have committed to providing aid to farms that have suffered losses – including aid for insurable crops such as wine grapes and strawberries. Late frosts and climate change There are very clear indications that climate change is bringing forward both the start of the vegetation period and the date of the last spring frost. Whether the spring frost hazard increases or decreases with climate change depends on which of the two occurs earlier. There is thus a race between these two processes: if the vegetation period in any given region begins increasingly earlier compared with the date of the last spring frost, the hazard will increase over the long term. If the opposite is the case, the hazard diminishes. Because of the different climate zones in Europe, the race between these processes is likely to vary considerably. Whereas the east is more heavily influenced by the continental climate, regions close to the Atlantic coastline in the west enjoy a much milder spring. A study has shown that climate change is likely to significantly reduce the spring frost risk in viticulture in Luxembourg along the River Moselle1. The number of years with spring frost between 2021 and 2050 is expected to be 40% lower than in the period 1961 to 1990. By contrast, a study on fruit-growing regions in Germany2 concluded that all areas will see an increase in the number of days with spring frost, especially the Lake Constance region, where reduced yields are projected until the end of this century. At the same time, however, only a few preliminary studies have been carried out on this subject, so uncertainty prevails. Outlook The spring frost in 2017 illustrated the scale that such an event can assume, and just how high losses in fruit growing and viticulture can be. Because the period of vegetation is starting earlier and earlier in the year as a result of climate change, spring frost losses could increase in the future, assuming the last spring frost is not similarly early. It is reasonable to assume that these developments will be highly localised, depending on whether the climate is continental or maritime, and whether a location is at altitude or in a valley. Regional studies with projections based on climate models are still in short supply and at an early stage of research. However, one first important finding is that the projected decrease in days with spring frost does not in any way imply a reduction in the agricultural spring frost risk for a region. So spring frosts could well result in greater fluctuations in agricultural yields. In addition to preventive measures, such as the use of fleece covers at night, sprinkler irrigation and the deployment of wind machines, it will therefore be essential to supplement risk management in fruit growing and viticulture with crop insurance that covers all natural perils. Source - ttps://www.munichre.com/

17.05.2014

Russia Livestock Overview: Cattle, Swine, Sheep & Goats

Private plots generate 48 percent of cattle, 43 percent of swine and 54 percent of sheep and goats in Russia.  The Russian government recently approved a new program that will succeed the National Priority Project in agriculture (NPP) titled, “TheState Program for Development of Agriculture and Regulation of Food and Agricultural Markets in 2008-2012,” that encourages pork and beef production and attempts to address Russia’s declining cattle numbers.  This program includes import-substitution policies designed to stimulate domestic livestock production and to protect local producers. In the beginning of 2007, the economic environment for swine production was generally unfavorable.  The average production cost was RUR40-45/kilo of live weight, while the farm gate price was RUR40/kilo live weight.  Pork producers have been expressing concern for years about sales after implementation of the NPP as pork consumption is growing at a slower rate than pork production.  As a result, the pork sector has been lobbying the Russian government to regulate imports in spite of the meat TRQ agreement. From January-September 2007, 1.38 million metric tons (MMT) of red meat was imported.  A 12-year decline in beef production has resulted in limited beef availability in the Russian market leading to a spike in prices.  In response, the Russian government has been force to take steps to increase the availability of beef by lifting a meat ban on Poland and by looking to Latin America for higher volumes of product.  Feed stocks decreased during the first 11 months of 2007 compared to the previous year which will likely create even greater financial problems for livestock operations in 2008 as feed prices continue to skyrocket.  Grain prices increased rapidly in Russia through the middle of July 2007 before stabilizing at high levels as harvest progress reports were released. The Russian pig crop is expected to increase by 6 percent in 2008, while cattle herds are predicted to decrease by 3.5 percent.  Some meat market analysts predict that by 2012, as new and modernized pig farming complexes reach planned capacity, pork production could reach 3.5 MMT – up 75 percent from 2008 estimates. According to the Russian Statistics Agency (Rosstat), 1/3 of all Russian “large farms” are unprofitable.  Many of these are involved in livestock production.  Small, inefficient producers are uncompetitive and have already begun disappearing from the market. The Russian veterinary service continues to playa decisive role in meat import supply management. Source - http://www.cattlenetwork.com

27.11.2012

Statistics Canada : Farm income, 2011

Realized net income for Canadian farmers amounted to $5.7 billion in 2011, a 53.1% increase from 2010. This rise followed a 19.0% increase in 2010 and a 19.6% decline in 2009. Realized income is the difference between a farmer's cash receipts and operating expenses, minus depreciation, plus income in kind. Realized net income fell in four provinces: Newfoundland and Labrador, Nova Scotia, Manitoba and British Columbia. In each, increases in costs outpaced gains in receipts. Farm cash receipts Farm cash receipts, which include market receipts from crop and livestock sales as well as program payments, rose 11.9% to $49.8 billion in 2011. This was the first increase since 2008. Market receipts alone increased 12.0% to $46.3 billion. Crop receipts, which increased 15.8% to $25.9 billion, contributed the most to the increase. Sales from livestock products rose 7.5% to $20.3 billion, the largest annual increase since 2005. Stronger prices for grains and oilseeds played a major role in the increase in crop revenues. For example, canola receipts increased 37.3% in 2011 on the strength of a 27.3% gain in prices. Grains and oilseed prices started rising in the last half of 2010 as a result of limited global stocks and strong demand. Even though prices peaked in mid-2011, prices for the year, on average, remained well above 2010 levels. Crop receipts rose in every province except Manitoba and Newfoundland and Labrador. In Manitoba, difficult growing conditions reduced marketings of most grains and oilseeds. In Prince Edward Island and New Brunswick, increases in potato prices and marketings helped push crop receipts higher. It was also stronger prices that were behind the rise in livestock receipts. Hog receipts increased 15.5% to $3.9 billion on the strength of a 14.7% price increase. Cattle prices rose 19.5% in 2011, while receipts increased 1.1% because of a reduced supply of market animals. Hog, cattle and calf prices increased in 2010. The upward trend continued throughout most of 2011, primarily because of low North American inventories and high feed grain costs. Receipts for producers in the three supply-managed sectors-dairy, poultry and eggs-increased 7.9% as rising prices reflected higher costs for feed grain and other production inputs. A 14.9% rise in chicken receipts exceeded increases for eggs (+8.7%) and dairy products (+5.3%). Program payments increased 11.2% to $3.5 billion in 2011. Increases in Quebec provincial stabilization payments as well as crop insurance payments in Manitoba and Saskatchewan accounted for much of the rise. Farm expenses Farm operating expenses (after rebates) were up 8.4% to $38.3 billion in 2011, the second-largest percentage increase since 1981. This increase followed two consecutive years of modest declines. Higher prices for fertilizer, feed and machinery fuel contributed to the increase in operating expenses. According to the Farm Input Price Index, both fertilizer and machinery fuel prices were up by over 25% in 2011. At the same time, feed grain prices increased by more than 30%. When depreciation charges were included, total farm expenses increased 8.2% to $44.1 billion. Depreciation costs rose 6.9%. Total farm expenses advanced in every province in 2011. The largest percentage increases occurred in Saskatchewan (+12.3%), Quebec (+9.5%) and Alberta (+9.0%). Total net income Total net income reached $5.8 billion, a $3.3 billion gain. There were large increases in Saskatchewan (+$2.1 billion), Alberta (+$567 million) and Ontario (+$470 million), while Newfoundland and Labrador, New Brunswick and Manitoba saw declines. Total net income adjusts realized net income for changes in farmer-owned inventories of crops and livestock. It represents the return to owner's equity, unpaid labour, and management and risk. The total value of farm-owned inventories rose by $165 million in 2011. A strong increase in deferred grain payments together with the first increase in cattle inventories since 2004 contributed to the rise. Note to readersRealized net income can vary widely from farm to farm because of several factors, including commodities, prices, weather and economies of scale. This and other aggregate measures of farm income are calculated on a provincial basis employing the same concepts used in measuring the performance of the overall Canadian economy. They are a measure of farm business income, not farm household income. Financial data for 2011 collected at the individual farm business level using surveys and other administrative sources will soon be tabulated and made available. These data will help explain differences in performance of various types and sizes of farms. For details on farm cash receipts for the first three quarters of 2012, see today's "Farm cash receipts" release. As a result of the release of data from the 2011 Census of Agriculture on May 10, 2012, data on farm cash receipts, operating expenses, net income, capital value and other data contained in the Agriculture Economic Statistics series are being revised, where necessary. The complete set of revisions will be released in the November 26, 2013, edition of The Daily. Table 1 Net farm income 2009 2010r 2011p 2009 to 2010 2010 to 2011 millions of dollars % change + Total farm cash receipts including payments 44,599 44,466 49,772 -0.3 11.9 - Total operating expenses after rebates 36,052 35,315 38,276 -2.0 8.4 = Net cash income 8,547 9,151 11,496 7.1 25.6 + Income-in-kind 39 40 45 2.6 11.1 - Depreciation 5,471 5,483 5,864 0.2 6.9 = Realized net income 3,115 3,709 5,677 19.0 53.1 + Value of inventory change -281 -1,157 165 ... ... = Total net income 2,834 2,551 5,842 ... ... Table 2 Net farm income, by province Canada Newfoundland and Labrador Prince Edward Island Nova Scotia New Brunswick Quebec millions of dollars 2010r + Total farm cash receipts including payments 44,466 118 407 500 479 7,171 - Total operating expenses after rebates 35,315 106 367 422 406 5,472 = Net cash income 9,151 12 41 78 73 1,699 + Income-in-kind 40 0 0 1 1 10 - Depreciation 5,483 8 41 59 54 727 = Realized net income 3,709 4 0 19 20 983 + Value of inventory change -1,157 -0 18 0 9 13 = Total net income 2,551 4 18 19 29 996 2011p + Total farm cash receipts including payments 49,772 120 477 527 533 7,967 - Total operating expenses after rebates 38,276 114 391 448 424 6,018 = Net cash income 11,496 6 86 79 109 1,949 + Income-in-kind 45 0 0 1 1 11 - Depreciation 5,864 9 43 62 55 767 = Realized net income 5,677 -2 43 18 55 1,194 + Value of inventory change 165 -0 -12 2 -50 -24 = Total net income 5,842 -3 31 20 5 1,170 Source - http://www.4-traders.com/

istanbul escort şişli escort tbilisi escort şişli escort şişli escort maslak escort istanbul escort beşiktaş escort taksim escort izmir escort ümraniye escort mecidiyeköy escort şişli escort taksim escort ümraniye escort kartal escort şirinevler escort maltepe escort istanbul escort ümraniye escort kadıköy escort vip escort mersin escort istanbul escorts ataköy escort avcılar escort beylikdüzü escort okmeydanı escort şişli escort tuzla escort işitme cihazı sex shop sex shop sex shop sex shop sex shop sex shop sex shop sex shop