Managing Agricultural Production Risk - Innovations in Developing Countries

03.01.2007 600 views
Managing Agricultural Production Risk - Innovations in Developing Countries

World Bank - Ulrich Hess, Jerry Skees, Andrea Stoppa, Barry Barnett, John Nash

Progress is being made in creating risk transfer markets for weather events in developing and emerging economies. While this document introduces several sources of risk that create poverty traps for poor households and that impede the development process, the focus is on low-probability, high-consequence weather risk events as they relate to rural households. These types of risks are highly correlated and require special financing and access to global markets to pool the risk and make them more diversifiable, improving the pricing. Thus, a significant contribution of this document is the introduction of index insurance and highlighting how it can be used at the micro-, meso-, and macro-levels for risk transfer. In particular, using index insurance products, it is possible to organize systems to take advantage of global markets and transfer out of developing countries the correlated risks associated with low-probability, high-consequence events. This document presents both a conceptual backdrop for understanding how this can be done and also a progress report on several World Bank efforts to assist countries in using limited government resources to facilitate market-based agricultural risk transfer for natural disasters. While global markets that provide reinsurance for natural disasters are both large and growing, they rarely have an interest in taking such risk from developing and emerging economies. In part this is because primary insurance markets are weak in developing countries. Before agreeing to provide reinsurance, global reinsurers engage in due diligence investigations of primary insurers and the risks the primary insurers wish to transfer. Compared to traditional insurance products, index insurance has far fewer hidden information and hidden action problems. This reduces the reinsurers due diligence and underwriting costs and makes it more likely that they will be interested in accepting natural disaster risk from new insurance providers in developing countries. Nonetheless, natural disaster losses can be significant, and carefully crafted ways to finance such losses are also critical preconditions for shifting the risk into global markets. Innovation in pooling these risks globally may also facilitate the transfer of natural disaster risk from developing countries.

 

 

For full version of the report please download the document (PDF, 700 kB) 

 

 

The World Bank

Agriculture and Rural Development Department

June 2005

 

Progress is being made in creating risk transfer markets for weather events in developing and emerging economies. While this document introduces several sources of risk that create poverty traps for poor households and that impede the development process, the focus is on low-probability, high-consequence weather risk events as they relate to rural households. These types of risks are highly correlated and require special financing and access to global markets to pool the risk and make them more diversifiable, improving the pricing. Thus, a significant contribution of this document is the introduction of index insurance and highlighting how it can be used at the micro-, meso-, and macro-levels for risk transfer. In particular, using index insurance products, it is possible to organize systems to take advantage of global markets and transfer out of developing countries the correlated risks associated with low-probability, high-consequence events. This document presents both a conceptual backdrop for understanding how this can be done and also a progress report on several World Bank efforts to assist countries in using limited government resources to facilitate market-based agricultural risk transfer for natural disasters. While global markets that provide reinsurance for natural disasters are both large and growing, they rarely have an interest in taking such risk from developing and emerging economies. In part this is because primary insurance markets are weak in developing countries. Before agreeing to provide reinsurance, global reinsurers engage in due diligence investigations of primary insurers and the risks the primary insurers wish to transfer. Compared to traditional insurance products, index insurance has far fewer hidden information and hidden action problems. This reduces the reinsurers due diligence and underwriting costs and makes it more likely that they will be interested in accepting natural disaster risk from new insurance providers in developing countries. Nonetheless, natural disaster losses can be significant, and carefully crafted ways to finance such losses are also critical preconditions for shifting the risk into global markets. Innovation in pooling these risks globally may also facilitate the transfer of natural disaster risk from developing countries.

 

One global innovation currently being prepared by the World Bank and European Commission involves a Global Index Insurance Facility (GIIF). The GIIF will have three functions that are targeted at helping developing country insurance providers build capacity: 1) supporting the technical assistance and infrastructure that are needed to develop index insurance using quality data; 2) aggregating and pooling risk from different developing countries to allow for improved pricing and risk transfer into the global reinsurance and capital markets; and 3) co-financing certain insurance products on a bi-lateral basis from donor to developing country. Importantly, the third function will be separate from the commercial activity represented in functions 1 and 2. A global effort to facilitate these three functions could represent a major breakthrough for developing countries that are exposed to extreme natural disaster risk.

 

Another promising realm of innovation is in the development of improved technology to both measure weather and to link weather and farming systems together to forecast crop yields. Improved and less costly systems for measuring weather events in developing countries will play a significant role in the potential success of many of the ideas presented in this document. Secure and accurate measurement will influence both the pricing of index insurance and the demand from end users. Improvements in measuring the vegetative cover with satellite images and then forecasting the value of that vegetation either in terms of crop yields or grazing value could enhance the type of index insurance products that are made available in developing countries. Additionally, more sophisticated crop models that link weather, management systems, and soil can be used to provide insurance products that protect against the dominant random variable in production — the weather.

 

There are numerous reasons why risk transfer out of developing countries is important. Natural disasters impede the development process, push households into poverty, and drain fiscal resources of developing countries. Many of these natural disasters are directly tied to extreme weather events. Bad weather events have devastating impacts on agriculture. Of the 1.3 billion people in the world who are living on less than US$1 per day, nearly three-fourths depend on agriculture for their livelihood. In many countries around the world, agricultural development will still clear the way for overall economic development of the broader economy. There is a strong link between weather, the livelihoods of the poor, and development.

 

Yet, there is a void in effective ex ante solutions for weather risks in developing countries. Instead,

developing countries, the World Bank, and the donor community are currently heavily exposed to natural disaster risk via ex post responses such as financial bailouts, debt forgiveness, and emergency response. None of these responses are optimal. They fail to provide an effective safety net for the poor; they can be inequitable, untimely, and create a dependency that has dire consequences.

 

If planning for, and financing of, extreme weather events occurs ex ante, access to both formal and informal lending should improve. As broader financial services become more accessible to the rural poor, newer technologies will be used and improvements in productivity and incomes should follow.

Farmers around the world utilize various risk coping and risk management strategies. However, many of these strategies are inefficient. The economic development literature is full of cases to illustrate how risk-averse, poor farmers often give up potentially higher incomes to reduce their exposure to risk. Both individual households and the larger society incur costs for smoothing consumption across income shocks. In many cases, the poor must resort to paying high interest rates for loans after a major income shock. Some argue that the poor cannot afford to purchase ex ante insurance protection against extreme weather events. However, the widespread use of ex post loans suggests otherwise. The challenge remains of how to make insurance against extreme weather events both more effective and affordable. Two major challenges obstruct the development of risk transfer markets for agricultural losses caused by extreme weather events: 1) organizing ex ante financing for highly correlated losses that result in extremely large financial exposure; and, 2) high transaction costs due to asymmetric information problems such as moral hazard and adverse selection. The latter also makes it nearly impossible to provide traditional agricultural insurance for small farmers given large fixed transaction costs. This greatly increases the average cost, per monetary unit, of insurance protection for smallholder agriculture.

 

Unfortunately, there are few successful examples to consider. Governments in developed countries have provided heavily subsidized crop insurance that is both costly and questionable in terms of net social welfare.

 

In addition to these challenges, traditional agricultural insurance markets often generate low levels of purchase because the potential insurance purchasers’ willingness to pay for the insurance contract is less than the insurers’ willingness to accept. Researchers frequently find that economic decision makers underestimate the likelihood and/or magnitude of low-probability, high-consequence loss events. This reduces their willingness to pay for insurance that protects against these events. At the same time, because they have little empirical information about the likelihood and/or magnitude of extreme events, insurers tend to add large extra costs to premium rates for insurance products that protect against low-probability, high-consequence loss events. This divergence between what potential purchasers are willing to pay, and what insurers are willing to accept, causes agricultural insurance markets to clear at less than socially optimal quantities of risk transfer.

 

New conceptual models are being developed to facilitate the transfer of extreme weather risk out of developing countries. This document reports on the progress of several ongoing efforts of the Commodity Risk Management Group (CRMG) at the World Bank that have been motivated by these models. All of these efforts are built on the premise that index-based insurance products can effectively address both the challenge of ex ante financing of highly correlated losses and the challenge of high transaction costs.

 

Index insurance products pay indemnities based on an independent measure that is highly correlated with realized losses. Unlike traditional crop insurance that attempts to measure individual farm yields, index insurance makes use of variables that are largely exogenous to the individual policyholder, such as area yield, or weather events, such as temperature or rainfall. This feature greatly reduces the need for deductibles and copayments since there is very little exposure to asymmetric information problems such as moral hazard and adverse selection. Because there is no need for farm-level loss adjustment, index insurance products also have lower transaction costs than traditional agricultural insurance products. Purchasers of index insurance products are exposed to basis risk. Since index insurance indemnities are triggered not by farm-level losses but rather by the value of an independent measure (the index), it is possible for a policyholder to experience a loss and yet receive no indemnity. Conversely, it is possible for the policyholder to not experience a loss and yet, receive an indemnity. The effectiveness of index insurance as a risk management tool depends on how positively correlated farm-level losses are with the underlying index. Importantly, since farmers have incentives to continue to produce or try to save their crops and livestock, even during bad weather events, index insurance should provide for a more efficient allocation of resources.

 

Since they are standardized and transparent, index insurance products can also function as reinsurance instruments that transfer the risk of widespread correlated agricultural production losses. To the extent that institutions can be created to aggregate and pool the low-probability, high-consequence tail risk that results from writing insurance on these events, the divergence between insurers’ willingness to accept and potential purchasers’ willingness to pay should decrease, causing the market to clear at high quantities of risk transfer.

 

This document is written to inform a broad range of decision makers about progress that is being made in risk transfer for natural disaster risk. While the focus is on agriculture, obviously many of the same concepts can be used for other sectors that are exposed to natural disaster risk. Two basic innovations dominate the conceptual framework: 1) use of index-based insurance; and 2) layering risk to facilitate risk transfer. In many cases, individuals will self-insure against the layer of risk that is composed of high probability, low-consequence losses. Some form of government intervention may be required to achieve higher levels of risk transfer in the layer of risk that is composed of low-probability, high-consequence losses. Between these two extremes is a layer of risk that, with appropriate risk transfer and pooling structures, can be transferred using market mechanisms.

 

Since catastrophe risks (CAT risks) are one of the impediments to market development, a framework for government action in the management of agricultural risk that includes models for government intermediation of catastrophic risk through Government Disaster Options for CAT Risk (DOC) has been developed, proposing that governments buy index-based catastrophic risk coverage in international markets and offer them at rates that are lower than global market rates to local insurers who would pass these savings on to end users in developing countries. This would mitigate large loss/infrequent risks that are usually difficult and expensive to reinsure in traditional reinsurance markets, and would ultimately allow local insurers to cover more people against the extreme risks in an ex ante fashion.

 

Several case studies are presented to illustrate how these concepts are being applied in countries around the world. While the specifics vary based on the needs of each country, all of the cases involve the use of index insurance and/or layering of risk to facilitate risk transfer. The final chapter of this document describes potential future roles for the World Bank in the area of agricultural risk management.

 

This document presents innovations in agricultural risk management for natural disaster risk, with the focus on defining practical roles for governments of developing countries and the World Bank in developing risk management strategies. Recent success stories demonstrate that the World Bank can play a role assisting countries with effective actions that use limited government resources to facilitate market-based agricultural risk transfer. This is important, as developing countries, the World Bank, and the donor community are currently heavily exposed to natural disaster risk without the benefit of ex ante structures to finance losses. Instead, at each big drought or other natural disaster, there is an appeal for financial support, leaving the vulnerable to the mercy of ad hoc responses from government, the international financial institutions, and donors. In most developing countries, livelihoods are not insured by international insurance/reinsurance providers, capital markets, or even government budgets. In addition, natural disasters and price risk in agriculture also impede development of both formal and informal banking. Without access to credit, risk-averse poor farmers are locked in poverty with old technology and an inefficient allocation of resources.

 

Advances in risk transfer in developed countries are leading the way to solving many social problems. Shiller (2003) documents progress, and charts a course for far more innovation as the democratization of finance and technology spur global risk pooling. Financial and reinsurance markets in developed countries are rapidly developing index-based instruments that allow for the transfer of systemic risks and even livelihood risks. Innovations in risk transfer for natural disasters have been well documented (Doherty, 1997; Skees, 1999b). The challenge is to make these innovations relevant in developing countries and facilitate knowledge and access.

 

Is the absence of formal risk transfer from natural disasters in developing countries inevitable? Clearly not; there are formal global markets for offsetting natural disaster risks and weather risks that are widely used in developed countries.3 This document demonstrates how these markets can be used to insure natural disaster risk in developing countries. Agricultural sectors in developing countries are much more exposed to the vagaries of weather than are those of richer countries, so this protection would be even more valuable to them.

 

Is it a luxury to offer insurance to poor people who lack proper roads or even safe drinking water?

Priorities must be set for any government. Careful consideration of the benefits and costs of different interventions is critical. Still, the poor are forced to make production decisions with the objective of minimizing risk, rather than maximizing profits, foregoing more remunerative activities that could provide an escape from poverty. An effective and timely insurance mechanism might allow people to engage in higher risk/higher return activities without putting their livelihoods at risk. Spurring development via improved financial markets is an important activity in developing countries.

 

Are there any effective precedents for agricultural insurance mechanisms in developing countries? While these innovations are just taking hold, progress has been made with weather insurance for farmers in India, Ukraine, Nicaragua, Malawi, Ethiopia, and Mexico. Several other experiments are also documented in this work. Weather-insured farmers in India say they either have a good crop — in which case it does not matter if they do not recoup the insurance premium — or they have a monsoon failure, in which case they receive an insurance payout. This will at least cover their cash outlays and perhaps some extra money that allows them to keep children in school and preserve assets that otherwise would have to be liquidated at greatly reduced prices. These farmers will be likely to invest a little more in the right seeds and fertilizer at the right time. Quantifying this impact is difficult right now, but a large impact assessment will soon provide more information. It is clear already that when offered the choice, many farmers will pay for fully priced weather insurance in India. Even farmers who have access to the government-subsidized crop insurance product choose to buy the market-priced weather insurance product. They say they like the objective nature of the weather index; they can go and check the weather station measurements themselves. They also like the timely payout. Indeed, on this count, the new rainfall index insurance that pays on a timely basis compares favorably to the national crop insurance product that might pay after 18 months.

 

Is this only for large commercial farmers? One true advantage of weather insurance is that it can be targeted to small farmers as no monitoring is needed to verify farm-level losses. The Indian experience demonstrates that small farmers find value in weather insurance. BASIX (a microfinance entity in Andhra Pradesh) estimates that all of the 427 farmers who bought weather insurance policies in 2003 are small and medium-sized farmers with 2-10 acres of land and an average yearly income of 15,000-30,000 Rupees, or between US$1 and US$2 per day. Currently, many of those buying weather insurance in India are repeat customers. Clearly, these farmers were not too poor to buy the product. Early survey results demonstrate that over one-half list managing risk as the number one reason for buying the insurance. Some farmers might have chosen this new insurance option over the prospect of having to turn to a high interest money lender when cash is needed after a harvest failure.

 

Is this sustainable? Now that the pilot program in India is in its third year, other insurance companies have replicated and sold the product, and BASIX has mainstreamed the weather insurance product and automated delivery to an expected 8,000 clients for the 2005 season. Countries in Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America are starting their own weather insurance projects at micro-and macro-levels. For example, weather insurance-based drought emergency responses are being piloted in Ethiopia. Furthermore, weather insurance seems to be a good business. The Indian weather insurance program has emerged without the support of government subsidies. The Commodity Risk Management Group (CRMG) of the World Bank has advised those who were ready, to try these new approaches to agricultural risk management.

 

How can this be operationalized in the World Bank and elsewhere? Task managers and practitioners may have a desire to follow this work with potential projects — but how does one get started? This document presents ideas on how to begin with a solid framework of action. There are important public goods that governments and the World Bank could provide: for example, weather stations and risk financing for catastrophic protection.

Governments in drought-prone countries, and donors and relief agencies, should also be aware of the potential for other kinds of projects using risk management markets to improve the response to weather-related shocks. This document explores how current ad hoc disaster relief mechanisms can be modified and complemented by a more systematic response to recurrent droughts.

 

In assessing proper roles for government, one must first consider the economic benefits that can be

created by risk management tools, the characteristics of risks faced by farmers in a specific area, and the challenges associated with creating and maintaining risk management tools such as insurance. In general, there is no “one-size-fits-all” policy recommendation for the role of government in agricultural risk management. We assume that most governments consider at least four criteria when considering alternatives for addressing agricultural risk management needs: 1) fiscal constraint; 2) growth; 3) market-oriented risk-transfer; and 4) the social goal to reduce poverty and vulnerability in rural areas.

 

Chapter 2 of the document begins with an overview of risk and how decision makers currently cope with and manage risk in developing countries, and also carefully examines the impediments to developing effective risk transfer markets. High transaction costs, problems with correlated risk, and the classic problems of moral hazard and adverse selection clearly increase the cost of traditional insurance.

 

Chapter 3 reviews in detail the experience of some developed countries. A clear message about the government cost and inefficiencies of these systems further supports the need for finding new solutions for developing countries. The stark contrast between what is possible in a developed country versus a developing country motivates a search for new solutions.

 

Chapter 4 gives insight into alternative solutions that might be possible by introducing the concept of weather index insurance that insures against weather events that create serious agricultural losses. This chapter highlights the advantages of such systems for a developing country.

 

Chapter 5 brings together two core innovations: 1) the use of index insurance to insure against detrimental weather events with significantly lower monitoring costs; and 2) the use of layering insurance products to segment risk in a more efficient fashion allowing for risk transfer of correlated risk. These innovations provide a rich framework for introducing new approaches for risk sharing and risk transfer in developing countries, and outline an effective role for the World Bank and other donors in this important domain of natural hazard risk management.

 

Chapter 6 provides an overview of a number of pilot programs and case studies for countries that are ongoing.

 

Finally Chapter 7 makes recommendations for the role of the World Bank and country governments in facilitating the development of innovation in agricultural risk management.

 

 

DEVELOPED COUNTRY APPROACHES TO AGRICULTURAL RISK

 

To better understand agricultural risk management markets and government policies to facilitate access to risk management instruments, it is worthwhile to critically analyze the experiences of some developed countries. The experiences of the United States, Canada, and Spain are described for reference purposes, but it is important to understand why these systems may not be replicable or suitable in most developing countries. Nonetheless, it is important to recognize that many developed countries have more involved market support and income transfer programs that extend well beyond crop insurance. To the extent that these more complex programs are based on farm income, they also involve levels of protection for severe crop failures. The European community has extensive policies that focus on income protection.

 

CROP INSURANCE PROGRAMS IN DEVELOPED COUNTRIES

 

This section presents overviews of agricultural risk management programs in three developed countries: the United States, Canada, and Spain. These countries have been able to implement substantial programs to reduce yield and revenue risk for agricultural producers. While these programs offer a variety of risk management products for farmers, the programs also require significant government support that is not feasible for most countries.

 

The United States

 

In the United States, multiple-peril yield and revenue insurance products are offered through the Federal Crop Insurance Program (FCIP), which is a public/private partnership between the federal government and various private-sector insurance companies.10 The program seeks to address both social welfare and economic efficiency objectives. With regard to social welfare, the private companies that sell federal crop insurance policies may not refuse to sell insurance to any eligible farmer — regardless of past loss history. At the same time, the program aims to be actuarially sound.

 

Policies are available for over 100 commodities but in 2004 just four crops — corn, soybeans, wheat, and cotton — accounted for approximately 79 percent of the US$4 billion in total premiums. Excluding pasture, rangeland, and forage, approximately 72 percent of the national crop acreage is currently insured under the FCIP. About 73 percent of total premiums are for revenue insurance policies, while 25 percent are for yield insurance policies.

 

Most FCIP policies trigger indemnities at the farm (or even sub-farm) level. Yield insurance offers are based on a rolling 4-10–year average yield known as the Actual Production History (APH) yield. The federal government provides farmers with a base catastrophic yield insurance policy, free of any premium costs. Farmers may then choose to purchase, at federally subsidized prices, additional insurance coverage beyond the catastrophic level. This additional coverage, often called “buy-up” coverage, may be either yield or revenue insurance. Farm-level revenue insurance offers are based on the product of the APH yield and a price index that reflects national price movements for the particular commodity. Area-yield and/or area-revenue buy-up insurance policies are offered through the FCIP for some crops and regions. The areas for these policies are defined along county boundaries. On a per acre insured basis, area-level insurance products tend to be less expensive than farm-level insurance products. Thus, in 2004, area-yield and area-revenue policies accounted for 7.4 percent of total acreage insured but less than 3 percent of total premiums.

 

The federal government also provides a reinsurance mechanism that allows insurance companies to determine (within certain bounds) which policies they will retain and which they will cede to the government. This arrangement is referred to as the standard reinsurance agreement (SRA). The SRA is quite complex with both quota-share reinsurance and stop losses by state and insurance pool, however, in essence, it allows the private insurance companies to adversely select against the government. This is considered necessary since the companies do not establish premium rates or underwriting guidelines but are required to sell policies to all eligible farmers.

 

There are four components of federal costs associated with the U.S. program:

 

1. Federal premium subsidies range from 100 percent of total premium for catastrophic (CAT) policies to 38 percent of premium for buy-up policies at the highest coverage levels. Across all FCIP products and coverage levels, the average premium subsidy in 2004 was 59 percent of total premiums.

 

2. The federal government reimburses administrative and operating expenses for the private insurance companies that sell and service FCIP policies. This reimbursement is approximately 22 percent of total premiums.

 

3. The SRA has an embedded federal subsidy with an expected value of about 14 percent of total premiums.

 

4. The program, by law, is allowed to be called actuarially sound at a loss ratio of 1.075. This implies an additional federal subsidy of 7.5 percent of total premiums. On average, the federal government pays approximately 70 percent of the total cost for the FCIP. Farmer paid premiums account for only about 30 percent of the total cost. While the direct-farmer subsidy varies by coverage level, the U.S. has consistently passed legislation to increase the subsidy level to farmers for crop and revenue insurance products. The rate of subsidy is one component that has influenced the growth in overall premium. Figure 3.1 clearly shows that the growth in premium subsidy is greater than the growth in farmer paid premiums. The rate of subsidy was increased in 1995 and 2001.

 

Canada

 

In 2003 Canada revised its agricultural risk management programs. The “Business Risk Management” element of the new Agricultural Policy Framework (APF) is composed of two main schemes: Production Insurance and Income Stabilization.

 

The Production Insurance (PI) scheme offers producers a variety of multiple-peril production or production value loss products that are similar to many of those sold in the United States. One major distinction, however, is that the Canadian program is marketed, delivered, and serviced entirely and jointly by federal and provincial government entities, although it is the provincial authorities who are ultimately responsible for insurance provision. This allows provinces some leeway in tailoring products to fit their regions and to offer additional products.

 

Production insurance plans are offered for over 100 different crops, and provisions have been made to include plans for livestock losses as well. Crop insurance plans are available, based on individual yields (or production value in the case of certain items, such as stone-fruits) or area-based yields. Unlike the U.S. program, Canadian producers are not allowed to separately insure different parcels, but rather must insure together all parcels of a given crop type. This means that low yields on one parcel may be offset by high yields on another parcel when determining whether or not an overall production loss has occurred.

 

Insurance can also be purchased for loss of quality, unseeded acreage, replanting, spot loss, and emergency works. The latter coverage is a loss mitigation benefit meant to encourage producers to take actions that reduce the magnitude of crop damage caused by an insured peril.

 

Cost sharing between the federal government and each province for the entire insurance program is to be fixed at 60:40, respectively, by 2006. However, federal subsidies as a percentage of premium costs vary from 60 percent for catastrophic loss policies to 20 percent for low deductible production coverage. Combined, federal and provincial governments cover approximately 66 percent of program costs, including administrative costs. This is roughly equivalent to the percentage of total program costs borne by the federal government in the United States program. Provincial authorities are responsible for the solvency of their insurance portfolio. In Canada, the federal government competes with private reinsurance firms by offering deficit financing agreements to provincial authorities.

 

Beginning in 2004, the Canadian Agricultural Income Stabilization (CAIS) scheme replaced and integrated former income stabilization programs. CAIS is based on the producer production margin, where a margin is “allowable farm income,” that includes proceeds from production insurance, minus “allowable (direct production) expenses.” The program generates a payment when a producer’s current year production margin falls below that producer’s reference margin, which is based on an average of the program’s previous five-year margins, less the highest and lowest. One important feature of CAIS is that producers must participate in the program with their own resources. In particular, a producer is required to open a CAIS account at a participating financial institution and deposit an amount based on the level of protection chosen (coverage levels go from 70 percent to 100 percent of the “reference margin”). Once producers file their income tax returns, the CAIS program administration uses the tax information to calculate the producer’s program year production margin. If the program year margin has declined below the reference margin, some of the funds from producers’ CAIS account will be available for withdrawal.

 

Governments match the producers’ withdrawals in different proportions for different coverage levels. The total investment by federal and provincial governments for the “business risk management” programs is CAN$1.8 billion per year. In 2004 around CAN$600 million were provided by governments as insurance premium subsidies.

 

Spain

 

The Spanish agricultural insurance system is structured around an established public/private partnership. On the public side is the National Agricultural Insurance Agency (ENESA) that coordinates the system and manages resources for subsidizing insurance premiums, and the Insurance Compensation Agency (Consorcio de Compensación de Seguros) that, together with private reinsurers, provides reinsurance for the agricultural insurance market. Local governments are involved only to the extent that they are allowed to augment premium subsidies offered at the national level. On the private side, insurance contracts are sold by Agroseguro, a coinsurance pool of companies that aggregates all insurance companies active in agriculture. Farmers, insurers, and institutional representatives are all part of a general commission hosted by ENESA that functions as the managing board of the Spanish agricultural insurance system.

 

Similar to the United States and Canada, insurance policies offered cover multiple perils in a combined program. Policies are available for crops, livestock, and aquaculture activities, with these risks being pooled across the country by Agroseguro. Unlike the United States and Canada, farmer associations are more actively involved in implementation and development of agricultural insurance. Government has reserves to cover extreme losses, and as a final resort, the government treasury is used to cover losses that may occur beyond these reserves.

 

Total premiums for agriculture insurance policies purchased reached around US$550 million (?490 million) in 2003, of which approximately US$225 million (?200 million) have been provided by the government (Burgaz 2004). The rationale for subsidizing agricultural insurance is that it will serve as a disincentive for the government to also provide free ad hoc disaster assistance. To reinforce the point, Spanish producers are not eligible for disaster payments for perils for which insurance is offered. For non-covered perils, ad hoc disaster payments are available, but only if the producer had already purchased agricultural insurance for covered perils.

 

WHY THE EXPERIENCE OF DEVELOPED COUNTRIES IS NOT A GOOD MODEL FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

 

There are various reasons for developing countries to avoid adopting approaches to risk management similar to the ones adopted in developed countries. Clearly, developing countries have more limited fiscal resources than developed countries. Even more importantly, the opportunity cost of those limited fiscal resources may be significantly greater than those of a developed country. Thus, it is critical for a developing country to consider carefully how much support is appropriate and how to leverage limited government dollars to spur insurance markets. In developed countries, government risk management programs are as much about income transfers as they are about risk management. Developing countries cannot afford to facilitate similar income transfers to large segments of the population who may be engaged in farming. Nonetheless, since a larger percentage of the population in developing countries is typically involved in agricultural production or related industries, catastrophic agricultural losses will have a much greater impact on GDP than in developed countries.

 

Policy makers should also carefully consider the structural characteristics of agriculture for different countries. In general, farms in developing countries are significantly smaller than farms in countries like the United States and Canada. For traditional crop insurance products, smaller farms typically imply higher administrative costs as a percentage of total premiums. A portion of these costs are related to marketing and servicing (loss adjustment) insurance policies. Another portion is related to the lack of farm-level data and cost effective mechanisms for controlling moral hazard.

 

Developing countries also have far less access to global crop reinsurance markets than do developed countries. Reinsurance contracts typically involve high transaction costs related to due-diligence. Reinsurers must understand every aspect of the specific insurance products being reinsured (for example, underwriting, contract design, ratemaking, and adverse selection and moral hazard controls). Some minimum volume of business, or the prospect for strong future business, must be present to rationalize incurring these largely fixed transaction costs. The enabling environment to gain confidence in contract enforcement and the institutional regulatory environment are critical to create trust that must be present for a global reinsurer to become involved. These components are largely missing in developing countries.

 

In fact, a prerequisite for effective and efficient insurance markets is an enabling environment. Setting rules assuring that premiums will be collected and that indemnities will be paid is not a trivial undertaking. In this respect, the alternative risk management products discussed in Chapter 5 are structured to overcome many of these problems.

 

 

INNOVATION IN MANAGING PRODUCTION RISK: INDEX INSURANCE INDEX INSURANCE ALTERNATIVES

 

Given the problems with some traditional crop insurance programs in developed countries, it has been critical to search for new solutions that would mitigate several aspects of the problems outlined above. Index insurance products offer some potential to this end (Skees et al. 1999). Index insurance products are contingent claims contracts that are less susceptible to some of the problems that plague multiple-peril farm-level crop insurance products. With index insurance products, payments are based on an independent measure that is highly correlated with farm-level yield or revenue outcomes. Unlike traditional crop insurance that attempts to measure individual farm yields or revenues, index insurance makes use of variables that are exogenous to the individual policyholder — such as area-level yield, or some objective weather event such as temperature or rainfall — but have a strong correlation to farm level losses.

 

For most insurance products a precondition for insurability is that the loss for each exposure unit be uncorrelated (Rejda, 2001). For index insurance, a precondition is that risk be spatially correlated. When yield losses are spatially correlated, index insurance contracts can be an effective alternative to traditional farm-level crop insurance.

 

Index products also facilitate risk transfer into financial markets where investors acquire index contracts as another investment in a diversified portfolio. In fact, index contracts may offer significant diversification benefits, since the returns should be generally uncorrelated with returns from traditional debt and equity markets.

 

BASIC CHARACTERISTICS OF AN INDEX

 

The underlying index used for an index insurance product must be correlated with yield or revenue outcomes for farms across a large geographic area. In addition, the index must satisfy a number of additional properties that affect the degree of confidence or trust that market participants have that the index is believable, reliable, and void of human manipulation; that is, that measurement risk for the index is low (Ruck 1999). The properties for a suitable index are that the random variable being measured is:

 

1. observable and easily measured,

2. objective,

3. transparent,

4. independently verifiable,

5. able to be reported in a timely manner (Turvey 2002; Ramamurtie 1999), and

6. stable and sustainable over time.

 

Publicly available measures of weather variables generally satisfy these properties. For weather indexes, the units of measurement should convey meaningful information about the state of the weather variable during the contract period, and are often shaped by the needs and conventions of market participants. Indexes are frequently cumulative measures of precipitation or temperature over a period of time. In some applications, average precipitation or temperature measures are used instead of cumulative measures.

New innovations in technology, including the availability of low-cost weather monitoring stations that can be placed in many locations and sophisticated satellite imagery, will expand the number of locations where weather variables can be measured, and also the types of measurable variables. Measurement redundancy and automated instrument calibration further increase the credibility of an index. The terminology used to describe features of index insurance contracts is more like that used for futures and options contracts rather than that used for other insurance contracts. For example, rather than referring to the threshold where payments begin as a trigger, index contracts typically refer to it as a strike. They also pay in increments called ticks.

 

Consider a contract that is being written to protect against deficient cumulative rainfall during a cropping season (for example, see Figure 4.1). The writer of the contract may choose to make a fixed payment for every 1 mm of rainfall below the strike. If an individual purchases a contract where the strike is 100 mm of rain and the limit is 50 mm, the amount of payment for each tick would be a function of how much liability is purchased. There are 50 ticks between the 100 mm strike and 50 mm limit. Thus, if $50,000 of liability were purchased, the payment for each 1 mm below 100 mm would be equal to $50,000/ (100-50), or $1,000.

 

Once the tick and the payment for each tick are known, the indemnity payments are easy to calculate. For example, if the realized rainfall is 90 mm, there are 10 ticks of payment at $1,000 each; the indemnity payment will equal $10,000. Figure 4.1 maps the payout structure for a hypothetical $50,000 rainfall contract with a strike of 100 mm and a limit of 50 mm.

 

In developed countries, index contracts that protect against unfavorable weather events are now sufficiently well developed that some standardized contracts are traded in exchange markets. These exchange-traded contracts are used primarily by firms in the energy sector. However, the range of weather phenomena that can potentially be insured using index contracts appears to be limited only by imagination and the ability to parameterize the event. A few examples include excess or deficient precipitation during different times of the year, insufficient or damaging wind, tropical weather events such as typhoons, various measures of air temperature, measures of sea surface temperature, El Niño- Southern Oscillation (ENSO) that are tied to El Niño and La Niña, and even celestial weather events such as disruptive geomagnetic radiation from solar flare activity. Contracts are also designed for a combination of weather events, such as snow and temperature (Dischel 2001; Ruck 1999). The potential for the use of index insurance products in agriculture is significant (Skees 2001).

 

A major challenge in designing an index insurance product is minimizing basis risk. Basis risk refers to the potential mismatch between index triggered payouts and actual losses. It occurs when an insured has a loss and does not receive an insurance payment sufficient to cover the loss (minus any deductible), or when an insured has a loss and receives a payment that exceeds the amount of loss.

 

Since index insurance indemnities are triggered by exogenous random variables, such as area-yields or weather events, an index insurance policyholder can experience a yield or revenue loss and not receive an indemnity. The policyholder may also not experience a yield or revenue loss and yet, receive an indemnity. The effectiveness of index insurance as a risk management tool depends on how positively correlated farm-yield losses are with the underlying index. In general, the more homogeneous the area, the lower the basis risk and the more effective area-yield insurance will be as a farm-level risk management tool. Similarly, the more a given weather index actually represents weather events on the farm, the more effective the index will be as a farm-level risk management tool.

RELATIVE ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES OF INDEX INSURANCE

 

Index insurance can sometimes offer superior risk protection compared to traditional, farm-level, multiple-peril crop insurance. Deductibles, co-payments, or other partial payments for loss are commonly used by farm-level, multiple-peril insurance providers to mitigate asymmetric information problems such as adverse selection and moral hazard. Asymmetric information problems are much lower with index insurance because 1) a producer has little more information than the insurer regarding the index value, and 2) individual producers are generally unable to influence the index value. This characteristic of index insurance means there is less need for deductibles and co-payments. Similarly, unlike traditional insurance, there is little reason to place restrictions on the amount of coverage an individual purchases. As long as the individual farmer cannot influence the realized value of the index, there is no need to restrict liability.

 

An exception occurs when governments offer premium subsidies as a percentage of total premiums. In this case, they may want to restrict liability (and thus, premium) to limit the amount of subsidy paid to a given policyholder.

 

As more sophisticated systems (such as satellite imagery) are developed to measure events that cause widespread losses, it is possible that indexing major events will be more straightforward and accepted by international capital markets. Under these conditions, it may become possible to offer insurance in countries that traditional reinsurers and primary providers would previously have never considered. Insurance is about trust. New risk management opportunities can develop if relevant, reliable, and trustworthy indexes can be constructed.

 

THE TRADE-OFF BETWEEN BASIS RISK AND TRANSACTION COSTS

 

Among the most significant issues for any insurance product is the question of how much monitoring and administration is needed to assure that moral hazard and adverse selection are kept to a minimum. To accomplish this goal, principles of coinsurance and deductibles are used to make certain that the insured is sharing the risk and that mistakes in offering too generous a coverage will be mitigated. More information is needed to tailor insurance products and to minimize the basis risk for even an individual insurance contract. More information and more monitoring involve higher transaction costs which convert directly into higher premiums to cover the administrative costs of the insurance. Index insurance significantly reduces the transaction costs. Index insurance can also be written with lower deductibles and without the concern for introducing coinsurance. When farm yields are highly correlated with the index that is being used to provide insurance, offering higher levels of protection can result in risk-transfer superior even to individual multiple-peril crop insurance (Barnett et al., 2005).

 

The direct trade-off between basis risk and transaction costs has implications for product designs that are sustainable and for the role of government and markets. Chapter 5 introduces the idea of layering risk.

 

These concepts also greatly depend on understanding the trade-off between basis risk and transaction costs. At every level of risk transfer, someone must accept a certain degree of basis risk if the products are to be both sustainable and affordable. In short, extremely high transaction costs must be paid for. The extra premium or cost to society for absorbing the extra costs can easily offset the basis risk that may have to be accepted to make the risk transfer of natural hazard risk more efficient.

 

WHERE INDEX INSURANCE IS INAPPROPRIATE

 

Index insurance contracts will not work well for all agricultural producers. There are many places in the world where agricultural commodities are grown in microclimates. For example, much of the coffee produced in the world is grown on the sides of mountains. Fruit such as apples and cherries will also be commonly grown in areas that can have very large differences in weather patterns within a few miles. In highly spatially heterogeneous production areas, basis risk will likely be so high as to make index insurance problematic. Under these conditions, index insurance will work only if it is highly localized, and/or if it can be written so that it protects only against the most extreme loss events. Even in these cases, it may be critical to tie the index insurance to lending since loans are one form of mitigating basis risk.

 

Over-fitting the data is another concern with index insurance. If one has a limited amount of crop-yield data, fitting the statistical relationship between the index and that limited data can become problematic. Small sample sizes and fitting regressions within the sample can lead to complex contract designs that may or may not be effective hedging mechanisms for individual farmers. Standard procedures that assume linear relationships between the index and realized farm-level losses may be inappropriate. While scientists are tempted to fit complex relationships to crop patterns, interviews with farmers may reveal more about what type of weather events are of most concern. When designing a weather index contract one may be tempted to focus on the relationship between weather events and a single crop. When it fails to rain for an extended period of time, many crops will be adversely impacted. Likewise, if it rains for an extended period of time, with significant cloud cover because of persistent rain during a critical photosynthesis period, a number of crops may also be adversely impacted.

 

Finally, when designing index insurance contracts, significant care must be taken to assure that the insured has no better information about the likelihood and magnitude of loss than does the insurer.

 

Forecasts of weather by farmers are many times quite accurate. Potato farmers in Peru forecast El Niño at least as well as many climate experts using celestial observations and other indicators in nature (Orlove et al., 2002). In 1988 an insurer offered drought insurance in the U.S. Midwest. As the sales closing date neared, the company noted that farmers were increasing the purchase of these contracts in a significant fashion. Rather than recognize that these farmers had already made a conditional forecast that the summer was going to be very dry, the company extended the sales closing date and sold even more rainfall insurance contracts. The company experienced very high losses and was unable to meet the full commitment of the contracts. Rainfall insurance for agriculture in the United States suffered a significant setback. The lesson learned is that if one is going to write insurance based on weather events, it is critical to be diligent in following and understanding weather forecasts and any information to make forecasts available to farmers. Farmers have a vested interest in understanding the weather and climate. Insurance providers who venture into weather index insurance must know at least as much as farmers about conditional weather forecasts. Otherwise, intertemporal adverse selection will render the index insurance product unsustainable. These issues can be addressed; typically, the sales closing date must be established in advance of any potential forecasting information that would change the probability of a loss beyond the norm. But beyond simply setting a sales closing, the insurance provider must have the discipline and systems in place to make certain that policies are not sold beyond that date.

 

POLICY OBJECTIVES

Governments that seek to spur growth and eradicate poverty almost inevitably mix economic policies that enhance efficiency and growth with social policies that address poverty and vulnerability. Governments often also pursue equity or income redistribution objectives. Thus, government policies related to agriculture and rural areas tend to pursue the following objectives:

 

1. Growth. Economic growth in rural areas — in particular higher agricultural yields and value-added processing, and also the development of off-farm activities — is perceived to be the best way out of poverty in the medium term. While better incentives for market players and an enabling infrastructure are key drivers, better management of agricultural production risk is also critical for growth, as it enhances access to credit and adoption of new technologies.

 

2. Reduce poverty and vulnerability in rural areas. Government directly intervenes in a targeted manner for social and equity reasons because free markets do not necessarily alleviate poverty for those in society who cannot participate effectively in these markets. Safety nets are one tool for such government intervention.

 

Given limited resources in developing countries and the existence of other sectors that require government attention, these objectives are typically pursued within an environment of binding fiscal constraints. These objectives target different segments of people in rural areas and different risk profiles.

 

Growth objectives focus on increasing profitability so that less poor farmers can continue adopting production technologies even when high-frequency, low consequence loss events occur. Poverty reduction policies target the poor and seek to increase their average income, and decrease the volatility of their income and the likelihood of a risk event wiping out hard-won asset gains.

 

A precondition for the sustainable achievement of growth and the objectives of poverty reduction is an ex ante system for disaster risk management. Disaster risk management covers severe and very infrequent events that affect mostly the poor, because the poor are more vulnerable and tend to live in marginal and more risk-exposed areas. Major natural disasters tend to trap people in poverty due to the lack of efficient risk management at the household level.22 Government disaster risk policies often entail some form of monetary compensation for the victims. The challenge is to deliver timely and predictable aid in disaster situations. This requires ex ante planning rather than just ex post disaster responses. This also implies efforts to forestall political demands for ex post, ad hoc government disaster assistance. Indeed, a credible and reliable disaster risk management system can put farmers and countries on a higher growth path as people are more comfortable in taking calculated and protected risks.

 

Naturally the growth and poverty-reduction objectives overlap, but that makes it even more important to clearly identify objectives, and design effective and cost-efficient ways to achieve them. Mixing the objectives can lead to sub-optimal outcomes. For example, many government-facilitated crop insurance programs attempt to simultaneously accomplish social welfare and economic efficiency objectives.

 

CONSTRAINTS IN AGRICULTURAL RISK MANAGEMENT

 

When making decisions about agricultural risk management programs, policy makers face a number of constraints. They must consider whether the benefits of such programs outweigh the costs, and if so, outweigh the net benefits offered by competing demands on public resources. They must construct the risk management program so as to minimize distortions in resource allocation and reduce opportunities for rent-seeking behavior. They must take into consideration the status and development of financial and insurance institutions within the country, any regulatory constraints on the operations of those institutions, and the infrastructure for enforcing contracts. Finally, it is important to consider the dichotomy that exists in many countries between smallholder farms and large farms that produce for export markets.

 

Cost-benefit analyses of agricultural risk management projects

 

Traditional economic analyses of projects (or other sector interventions) weigh social benefits against social costs, usually in monetary terms. In theory, this procedure should make it possible to compare the net benefits from these projects with the net benefit of a government risk management program. However, conducting such a comparison is not a trivial exercise, as the assumptions required to quantify the benefits of risk management are numerous and not always robust across different projects. Still, it is worthwhile to compare the net benefits of government risk management programs with the net benefits from other projects if only to get a sense of the orders of magnitude involved.

 

Fiscal constraints

 

Government expenses for agricultural insurance programs can be quite high. This is often masked in the way that actuarial performance is presented. Governments typically report loss ratios, or cost to premium ratios, as indemnities paid, divided by total premiums collected. There are two problems with this. First, because of government premium subsidies, farmers pay only a fraction of the total premium. Second, governments typically absorb most of the administrative and operating costs. When calculating loss ratios for private sector insurance products, administrative costs are included in the numerator. By simply looking at indemnity relative to premiums (and not being concerned that some significant portion of premiums are paid by the public sector) both the U.S. and Canadian crop insurance programs have, in recent years, reported loss ratios around 1.0. These loss ratios are then cited as evidence that the programs are actuarially sound. But if administrative and operating costs are added to the numerator and government premium subsidies are subtracted from the denominator so that the loss ratio is equivalent to the standard used for private sector insurance products, the crop insurance loss ratios are about 3.6 for the United States and 2.9 for Canada.23 Hazell (1992) estimates similar ratios for a number of government-based crop insurance programs. His estimates show the Philippines, Japan, and Brazil with programs where the loss ratios (as defined in the private sector) exceed 4.0.

 

Policy makers often suggest agricultural insurance programs as an alternative to free ex post disaster assistance. In principle, insurance programs have many advantages over ex post disaster assistance. For example, it is often argued that disaster assistance programs can generate perverse incentives that increase the magnitude of losses in subsequent disaster events (Barnett 1999; Rossi et al. 1982). But, in practice, agricultural insurance programs have often evolved into another vehicle for transferring wealth from the public sector to agricultural producers. Furthermore, there is not much evidence that agricultural insurance programs have been successful in forestalling free ex post government disaster assistance. For example, in the United States, more and more costly crop insurance programs have coexisted with disaster payments for well over 20 years (Glauber 2004).

 

Operational constraints: minimize distortions/rent-seeking opportunities

Governments should only choose to invest public resources in developing agricultural insurance if the social costs of inefficiencies caused by the lack of such insurance products outweigh the social costs of government intervention. These social costs would include not only the opportunity costs of public resources required to create and maintain the agricultural insurance products but also any resource allocation distortions that result from farmers and rural decision makers responding to incentives created by the insurance products. This can include rent-seeking and regressive effects of policies that benefit mostly large commercial farmers.

 

Contract enforcement

 

Contract enforcement is critical to effective and sustainable risk management programs. It is very difficult to develop insurance contracts if the legal and regulatory environment does not exist for contract enforcement. Purchasers will lose trust in the program if indemnity payments are not made on a timely basis or are frequently tied up in long-lasting legal procedures.24 Likewise, insurers will lose trust in the program if they are forced to pay indemnities for losses that the contract is not intended to cover.

 

Level of financial sector development

 

Complex agricultural insurance programs are not likely to be sustainable unless they are accompanied by adequate amounts of insurance capital and expertise. In developing countries, insurance sectors are often underdeveloped and concentrated in very few lines of business such as automobile, property, and casualty insurance. Further, insurance companies in developing countries tend to be based in urban areas. They tend to shy away from rural areas where the insurance market is characterized by high transaction costs and small policies.

 

New products will be required if agricultural insurance is to take root in countries with underdeveloped traditional insurance sectors. For example, insurance products that are based on an index that is recognized and accepted by international reinsurers provide opportunities to bypass in-country insurance capacity constraints. If the reinsurer accepts the data and settlement procedures for the index, the insurer’s capital is somewhat less relevant than for traditional lines of insurance because the reinsurer is not really accepting the insurer’s underwriting risk, but rather only the risk inherent in the index. Experience with reinsurance for weather index contracts reveals that reinsurers may even be willing to take 100 percent of the risk. However, for operational and regulatory reasons, international reinsurers prefer to deal with professionally-run companies to source the risk.

 

Structure of agricultural sectors

 

Smallholder-dominated agriculture is clearly a constraint for the large-scale roll-out of sophisticated crop insurance programs or indeed, any agricultural risk management scheme. Farmers with one hectare of land or less will never be an attractive marketing target for insurance companies. The challenge is to identify suitable aggregators of risk, such as microfinance institutions, banks or cooperatives, or even local authorities who can enroll farmers in group insurance programs. Agricultural sectors need to be segmented, and distribution channels tailor-made to specific needs and local customs.

 

Regulatory constraints

 

Agricultural risk transfer involves financial contracts that are regulated according to prudential principles. Insurance companies must organize the financing to pay for the worst case scenario. This constrains the type and sophistication of contracts — just as the capacity of the regulator to understand and supervise new products can be a constraint.

 

Spatial correlation of risk

 

Weather events that cause agricultural losses are often highly spatially correlated. In the presence of such spatial correlation, index insurance products, such as the rainfall index insurance described above, can be effective risk transfer mechanisms. However, once the risk is transferred from the farmer to a local insurance provider, spatial correlation makes it very difficult for the local insurance provider to generate much risk reduction through pooling. Unless some mechanism exists for transferring the spatially correlated loss risk out of the region or country, local insurance providers will be reluctant to offer insurance products — even if those products protect only against losses in the market insurance layer.

 

Risk-transfer strategies

 

There are at least three strategies for transferring risk from index insurance contracts: 1) direct transfer of contracts into reinsurance markets; 2) packaged transfer of independent contracts; and, 3) pooling of risk and subsequent transfer of the pool tail risk (Table 5.1). Under the first two strategies there is no basis risk, insofar as every single contract is reinsured against payouts that exceed a defined level. However, since no pooling occurs prior to the risk transfer, direct and packaged risk transfer strategies will likely have higher reinsurance premium rates than the transfer of pooled risks — even if the reinsurer offers portfolio-adjusted pricing. Under the third strategy of pooling risk prior to transfer, insurers could be exposed to some basis risk insofar as a pool of indexes does not perfectly reflect the payout likelihood of each individual contract, and only the excess risk of the overall pool is reinsured. However, if there are opportunities to diversify risks within the pool, this strategy could lead to lower reinsurance premiums relative to either of the other two strategies since the risk of the overall pool (rather than each individual contract) would be reinsured. The first strategy does not involve the government in transferring the risk.

 

The other two strategies may involve government in either facilitating risk transfer (second strategy) or pooling risk and facilitating risk transfer (third strategy).

 

Pooling of risk

 

The third risk transfer strategy identified above involves pooling risks within the country or region. Risk pooling is based on the statistical law of large numbers which states that the more uncorrelated risks that are added to a portfolio, the lower the variance in the outcomes of the overall portfolio. For an insurer, this results in lower capital needs and therefore lower capital costs.

 

Index-based insurance contracts can be pooled and transferred in a number of ways. For example, the reinsurance contract can be based on a basket index that is a weighted average of the indexes contained in the pool. A risk management program being considered for Malawi would have private insurers sell rainfall-based index insurance contracts for various weather stations around the country. The government would purchase reinsurance protection and sell it to the insurers. For reinsurance cover, the government could use the Malawi Maize Production Index (MMPI), a weighted average of weather station indexes with each station’s contribution weighted by the corresponding expected maize production from that location. The more highly spatially correlated the risks on the underlying indexes, the better the basket index will perform as a reinsurance mechanism (that is, the lower the reinsurance basis risk). But, of course, the more highly spatially correlated the risks on the underlying indexes, the less advantage there is to pooling within the country as opposed to simply transferring the underlying weather station indexes to the reinsurance market using either of the first two strategies identified above.

 

A pool of index insurance risks can also be transferred using traditional stop loss reinsurance. In this case, in exchange for a reinsurance premium, the reinsurer would simply cover all losses in excess of a predefined percentage (for example, 110 percent) of the total premium dollars in the pool. With this type of reinsurance (and unlike reinsurance based on a basket index), the pool would not be exposed to basis risk. However, the transactions costs for the reinsurer will be much higher since the reinsurer will need to conduct due diligence on not only the underlying indexes but also the underwriting of the pool. All other things equal, higher transactions costs will cause reinsurers to charge higher reinsurance premiums. Despite this, if spatial diversification opportunities are sufficiently high, pooling may reduce risk exposure to such an extent that reinsurance premium costs are reduced.

 

This concept can be extended to the pooling of multi-country risks within a region. Weather-risk can be retained and managed internally if the areas under management are significantly diverse in their weather risk characteristics. This immediately suggests that the weather sensitivity of neighboring countries must be taken into account when considering a country’s weather-risk profile and its need for outside reinsurance. Consider the example of the region of the Southern African Development Community (SADC; Figure 5.3). Analysis shows that on average, two countries in the region suffer a drought each year. However, the distribution of drought events in SADC is extremely long-tailed, with the possibility of widespread drought events that could potentially devastate the region.

 

A SADC pool of rainfall-based index insurance contracts could be constructed with each member country being charged an actuarially fair assessment of the risk transferred to the pool. Suppose the financial impact to the pool of four SADC countries experiencing simultaneous droughts is about US$80 million. The pool may wish to transfer the risk of losses beyond US$80 million to the international reinsurance market. This could be done in layers with, for example, one layer of US$80-350 million being transferred using reinsurance mechanisms. Losses in excess of US$350 million, as might occur with simultaneous droughts in 10 SADC countries, occur with a frequency of about one percent. Instruments such as catastrophe (CAT) bonds might be used to transfer this extreme layer. CAT bonds allow the transference of very large exposures into financial markets and often have tenures of up to three years. More efficient means of transferring risk implies that costs could be greatly reduced for the member countries by transferring risk as part of a regional strategy rather than by transferring the risk one country at a time. For example, the SADC pooling approach above would reduce insurance costs by 22 percent for one of the countries, Malawi, due to risk-pooling effects (Hess and Syroka, 2005). However, managing a pool requires a high degree of underwriting and actuarial sophistication. Reinsurers will conduct due diligence and will be very reluctant to write traditional excess of loss reinsurance unless they are convinced that the pool is being managed appropriately.

 

POLICY INSTRUMENTS

 

Risk layering provides an extremely helpful conceptual framework for thinking about government intervention in risk transfer markets. In the previous discussion of the market insurance layer, reference was made to situations where government packaging or pooling of risk could potentially reduce the transaction costs associated with risk transfer and thus the premiums paid by end users. We next consider other possible government interventions. Specifically, we address government facilitation of risk transfer in the market failure layer, the role of government subsidies in risk transfer markets, and potential uses of index insurance instruments to finance government disaster relief and safety net policies.

 

Government disaster option for CAT risk: a policy for the market failure layer

 

Cognitive failure and ambiguity loading occur primarily with events in the extreme tail of the loss distribution — previously mentioned as the market failure layer. For this reason, and as a substitute for ad hoc disaster relief payments, governments may decide to cofinance risk transfer mechanisms for these events. For example, the government could design Disaster Option for CAT risk (DOC) index reinsurance contracts for catastrophic risks. Returning to the example in Figure 5.2, a DOC could insure against rainfall less than 500 mm with a payment per tick of say, $50. Primary insurers could then offer coverage beyond the earlier imposed limit of 500 mm and transfer the catastrophic tail risk to the government using the DOC. Even if primary insurers are selling traditional crop insurance they could use a DOC to transfer part of the catastrophic tail risk in their portfolio of crop insurance policies. DOCs could be offered for a variety of strikes and settlement weather stations, as long as the coverage is for catastrophic risk layers and can be offset in international weather risk markets. The government could even offer other DOC indexes (for example, excess rainfall or wind speed) to reinsure other lines of insurance, such as property and casualty (see Figure 5.4).

 

The government would reinsure DOCs in international reinsurance or capital markets using any of the three risk transfer strategies described earlier. Since DOCs would address only extreme catastrophic loss events, reinsurance premium rates would likely contain an ambiguity load. Premiums could be subsidized to offset part of this ambiguity load so DOC purchasers would pay something closer to a pure premium rate. DOCs could be tailor-made to individual insurers needs, for example, DOCs could be based on individual weather stations or written as regional weighted average baskets of weather stations. Strikes should be set so that the DOC covers only infrequent events (for example, an expected frequency of 1-in-30 years or less). This is the domain of the probability distribution over which potential insurance purchasers tend to experience cognitive failure and insurance providers engage in ambiguity loading. Primary insurers and ultimately insured parties would pay a premium for this catastrophic protection, but significantly less than what the market would charge.

 

Those who reinsure DOC contracts will insist on verifying the credibility of the underlying indexes. The premium required to transfer the risk to international markets would provide a baseline from which to base DOC premium rates.

 

The risk-layering approach proposed here would institutionalize the social role of government in subsidizing extreme risk events at the local level. Premium rates could be subsidized to offset ambiguity loading. Furthermore, by organizing DOC contracts at the local level, isolated severe events that do not capture the attention of national policy makers could still have some structured assistance.

 

To summarize the major advantages of offering index-based DOCs:

 

1. DOC contract provisions established ex ante allow for better planning than ad hoc disaster payments.

2. DOCs provide a structure that provides more spatial and temporal equity in government disaster assistance.

3. DOCs facilitate commercial insurance product development by providing a means by which catastrophic risk layers can be effectively transferred into international markets.

4. DOCs can be subsidized to address the market failure associated with ambiguity loading and cognitive failure.

5. Governments can estimate their own DOC subsidy cost exposure based on actuarial estimates of the risk inherent in the index. Reinsurance coverage adds a market check on the credibility of the index and the adequacy of DOC premium rates.

6. While DOCs may be partially subsidized, end users still pay part of the cost to transfer the risk into international markets. This reduces the potential for perverse incentives that could encourage excessive risk taking.

 

Subsidies

 

Governments frequently subsidize agricultural insurance products. These subsidies take a variety of forms. The government may cofinance insurance purchasing with direct premium subsidies, or may reimburse primary insurers for administrative or product development costs, or may provide reinsurance at below market premium rates. Regardless of the form, government subsidies are generally designed to increase insurance purchasing by lowering the premiums charged to agricultural insurance purchasers.

 

Such subsidies are extremely controversial. They tend to benefit operators of larger farms more than operators of smaller farms. A wide range of stakeholders can and will engage in rent seeking once subsidies are introduced. Subsidies are costly to maintain and are subject to close scrutiny regarding the social costs versus the social benefits. Many times subsidies are provided based on the rationalization that markets for agricultural insurance are missing or incomplete without careful consideration of the core reasons why such market limitations exist. This document has carefully considered why agricultural insurance is missing or incomplete in many settings: adverse selection and moral hazard, high transaction costs, cognitive failure and ambiguity loading, and exposure to highly correlated loss events. Any government subsidies should be carefully targeted to address one of these specific sources of market failure. However, even then it may be that the costs of addressing that market failure are simply too high to justify use of limited government resources to that end.

 

Even when subsidies are carefully targeted, the resulting rents can be captured by politically powerful elites. Government insurance subsidies may crowd out demand for private-sector risk transfer instruments. The World Bank supports the development of financial institutions that operate profitably on a commercial basis by offering products and services that meet the needs of a wide range of clients, including the poor. Thus, any World Bank efforts to facilitate the provision of risk transfer instruments should be based on careful consideration of whether subsidies or grants can be provided without distorting or inhibiting the growth of private-sector financial markets.

 

Some types of subsidies are likely less distorting than others. Subsidies and grants for supporting financial intermediaries and financial infrastructure, such as technical assistance and data systems needed to develop effective index insurance products, are likely to be the least distorting. Beyond distortions in the markets, there are legitimate reasons for supporting infrastructure to improve market access among the rural poor. Finally, some public support for product development may be justifiable because of the free rider problem. It is costly to develop innovative insurance products. Yet it is difficult to recoup these costs in a competitive market. Any firm can simply copy the new product and compete without having to recover the product development costs. Furthermore, developing index insurance products is an area that is unfamiliar in many developing countries.

 

Examples of subsidies for financial intermediaries and infrastructure include:

• Providing technical assistance to financial intermediaries to improve systems that enhance efficiency, such as management information systems;

• Developing and introducing demand-driven products on a pilot basis;

• Helping develop or improve service delivery mechanisms that enable greater outreach into rural areas;

• Covering a portion of the cost of establishing new branches in areas that do not have financial intermediaries that serve the poor;

• Creating capacity within regulatory and supervisory bodies;

• Supporting the creation of industry associations;

• Developing training institutes and insurance information agencies;

• Supporting data for weather stations or other data that will be used to develop effective indexes; and

• Providing technical assistance to develop new products in an emerging market in developing countries.

 

Premium Subsidies

 

While it is common for developed countries to cofinance premiums for farmers with direct premium subsidies, these types of subsidies are particularly problematic. Generally, direct premium subsidies reflect income enhancement objectives as much or more than risk management objectives. Such subsidies are typically provided on a percentage basis. This clearly benefits higher risk areas relatively more than lower risk areas. Even attempts to subsidize to levels that represent a pure premium or expected loss basis may favor higher risk areas relatively more than lower risk areas since in a commercial market, premium rates for higher risk areas would likely contain higher catastrophic loads. Thus, any attempt to introduce premium subsidies will likely be distorting.

 

In principle, if subsidies are targeted to the “market failure layer” as described above, market distortions should be minimal. Given the ambiguity loading and cognitive failure that occur in this layer, carefully targeted subsidies (such as cofinancing of DOCs) may even be welfare enhancing. However, for the “market insurance layer,” subsidies should, in general, be avoided. If subsidies are provided in the “market insurance layer,” they should be targeted to reducing uncertainty loads in premium rates.

 

Commercial insurers will tend to load premium rates based on the quantity and quality of data used to generate pure premium rates. The better (worse) the data used to generate the pure premium rates, the lower (higher) the premium load. These loads could be offset with cofinancing from donors. However, here again, one would need to be very clear about the level of these subsidies and the intent.

 

NICARAGUA: A SEVEN-YEAR INCUBATION PERIOD

 

Country context and risk profile

 

The contribution of agriculture to the Nicaraguan GDP has been in decline but still remains a significant economic activity. In 2003 agriculture accounted for nearly 18 percent of the US$4.1 billion GDP of Nicaragua. The major commodities produced include coffee, meat, shrimp, corn, sugar, and beans. In Nicaragua, 30 percent of the population is involved in agricultural activities; however, agriculture has experienced little, and often negative growth since the 90s and Nicaragua has remained a net food importer of cereals and grains. Agricultural production is hindered by exposure to drought and flood risks.

 

Nicaragua is the World Bank’s first experience in recent history where the idea of rainfall insurance was seriously considered. Hazell and Skees provided the first feasibility study in the spring of 1998.

 

Subsequently, Skees and Miranda (1998) examined the issue in more detail and made specific recommendations about rainfall insurance in the major cereal production area of northwest Nicaragua where the major risk to cereal production is insufficient or excess rainfall. In this work, they suggest that rainfall index insurance contracts could be introduced and sold to individual farmers to hedge against the risk of both drought and excess rain. Nonetheless, they also point to the large hurdles in making such an introduction in a developing country. Four key recommendations are made for progressing with a plan to introduce a rainfall index insurance pilot and deemed necessary for the development and sustainability of the insurance scheme:

 

1. Analytical work and development of human capital. Extensive data analysis and modeling would be necessary to design and price the insurance contracts. It would be equally important to train Nicaraguans in these methods to develop the capacity within the country for future work.

 

2. Pilot development for demonstration, education, and evaluation. The first year of the pilot should start small and be targeted primarily at learning and demonstration. Education, marketing, and sales would be primary goals. Only three stations should be used in the first year: 1) Leon; 2) San Antonio; and 3) Chinandega. This market is contiguous and would cover no more area than 800 square kilometers. To obtain the most effective risk management, only those within 10 kilometers of the stations should purchase the rainfall contracts.

 

3. Infrastructure development and pilot expansion. During year one of the pilot, investments in additional, secure weather stations should be made to increase the density of stations within the original 800 square kilometer market area. By year two, the sales and exposure should increase to about US$10 million.

 

4. In-country project management and support. It is essential to have a key person in Nicaragua who can manage and support the pilot project. This person should know all aspects of the project and be active in every dimension of the project. One key goal of the individual will be to monitor the activity and give international reinsurers the comfort to participate in this activity. Beyond the pilot test area, this person should be willing to investigate other possibilities for new regions that may stand on their own with private support. Fostering similar activity in other regions will help entice the international reinsurance community. This person should also facilitate an active education program. Beyond the educational effort, there should be funds for advertising and promotion.

 

Some progress was underway in discussions within both the Nicaraguan public and private sectors on these concepts when Hurricane Mitch arrived with its devastation in October of 1998. After this event, the focus on World Bank efforts to provide technical assistance in Nicaragua shifted to developing an aggregate weather index that would provide disaster financing to the government of Nicaragua during severe events. The work developed to the point of a specific set of weather stations that were indexed into a single aggregate index for protecting against catastrophic risk. The index was even priced in the global reinsurance markets. Once the contract was priced, the government rejected the idea on the grounds that they did not need to purchase insurance because they could depend on the global community for assistance when major catastrophes occurred. At this point, no further activity on index insurance was pursued in Nicaragua. Nevertheless, a number of significant lessons learned from the Nicaraguan experience:

 

• It takes time to develop innovation. The literature on innovation emphasizes that it takes time to gain acceptance of new ideas. Innovation can take a full generation before it is widely accepted.

 

The Nicaraguan experience fits perfectly with this theory. While the original idea was presented seven years ago, new products that fit with the ideas presented are just being introduced. It is reasonable to think that part of the reason that Nicaragua is only now introducing these ideas is because other countries have ventured into this domain.

 

• There is an inherent moral hazard in expecting that countries will purchase catastrophic protection. The excellent work completed after Hurricane Mitch to develop a mechanism for the government of Nicaragua to indemnify catastrophic losses from extreme weather events was met with a cool reception. The government was likely correct in their evaluation that they did not need this type of protection since the global community has been very responsive with free aidafter major catastrophes.

 

• Linking index insurance to banking in Nicaragua is an excellent addition to work that is ongoing around the globe. Early indications are that the banks in Nicaragua have agreed to reduce interest rates for production loans when their farmers purchase the new weather index insurance products.

 

Nicaragua may be the first country where there is an explicit tie between interest rates and the amount of index insurance purchased. This is an important development in Nicaragua that should be evaluated to be more fully understood.

 

Proposed agricultural risk management structure

 

In November of 2004, CRMG responded to interest expressed by INISER for developing a local weather index insurance market for agriculture. CRMG provided technical assistance to analyze potential markets for a pilot project in 2005 and decided to concentrate on developing a pilot project for the groundnut sector to secure lending to the sector. Banks have expressed their interest to internalize some part of the risk reduction by lowering the interest rate, while also providing financing for the farmers to pay the premium as an incentive for a proactive financial risk management approach.

 

Armed with prototype contracts INISER/CRMG has launched consultations with end users, financial intermediaries, and the insurance regulator. Final contracts have been designed and priced by reinsurers, but still require approval from the regulator.

 

The government of Nicaragua had adopted a “wait-and-see" strategy, based on several previous failures to launch either traditional or weather index insurance for agriculture. It was not until the most recent proposal was being developed and the government could clearly see that there was interest and participation from the international financial markets, that the government opened the door for serious policy dialogue on the issue. In particular, the government has offered to support INISER in the implementation phase with economic resources as well as guidance to upscale the current pilot project.

 

This has open the door to work with several productive sectors, including small farmers, in a comprehensive context of economic development where insurance becomes a useful tool to facilitate investments in the sector.

 

MOROCCO EXPERIENCE

 

Country context and risk profile

 

In Morocco 47 percent of the total population and most of the poor live in rural areas. Agriculture plays a crucial role for rural livelihoods. On average, agriculture accounts for about 17 percent of the GDP, but this percentage fluctuates, mainly due to climatic—especially rainfall—variations. Moroccan agriculture is characterized by a dichotomy between the traditional and commercial sectors. The traditional sector consists of small farms in rain fed areas involved predominantly in cereal, legume, and livestock production. The commercial sector operates mainly in irrigated areas. Farm surveys indicate that about 70 percent of farms are small in size (under 5 hectares) and account for 23 percent of total land under cultivation. Farms less than 20 hectares (ha) in size represent 96 percent of the number of farms in operation. The average size of a farm in Morocco is 5.7 ha. Almost 90 percent of Moroccan agriculture is non-irrigated, and since most of the crops rely on adequate rainfall, this has translated to wide variations in yields and production. For example, the production of cereals fell from 9.5 million tons in 1994 to 1.6 million tons in 1995 due to drought.

 

Current response

 

In 1995 the Moroccan government activated the Programme Secheresse (Drought Program), a state sponsored insurance program managed by the local mutual agricultural insurance company (MAMDA) that addressed the drought problem through the implementation of a yield insurance scheme. The program, revised in 1999, is structured on the coverage of three revenue levels of 1,000, 2,000, and 3,000 Moroccan Dirhams (MAD) per hectare (ha). Payments are triggered by a ministerial declaration certifying the occurrence of drought. For the first revenue threshold, the payout is based on an area-yield base mechanism, while for the 2,000 and the 3,000 MAD/ha level, specific farm-yield assessments are required. The program proved to be popular but also affected by typical yield insurance problems such as high costs for supporting insurance premiums and severe management problems related to individual farm-yield assessment (Hess et al. 2003).

 

Proposed agricultural risk management structure

 

Given the limitations of the Drought Program, the Moroccan government agreed to participate in a World Bank research project aimed at exploring the feasibility of weather-based insurance as an alternative to traditional yield insurance. The investigations led the team project to conclude that a drought insurance program based on rainfall indexes could have potentially significant benefits over the current scheme, minimizing moral hazard and adverse selection risk and promoting a more rapid, streamlined pay-out process, in addition to increasing the potential interest of international reinsurers and capital markets in investing in the program. Based on analysis of rainfall and cereal-yield data across the country, the study determined that an index-based rainfall insurance product could be feasible in Morocco. Following the feasibility study, an international team sponsored by the IFC and the Italian Technical Assistance Trust Fund assisted MAMDA in structuring the insurance coverage to be launched as a pilot program in some cereal growing regions.

 

Products

 

The structure of the product proposed for implementation was that of a rainfall index insurance contract that would indemnify cereal producers when the rainfall index in a determined area would fall below a specified threshold.

 

The indexes, developed by local agronomists together with farmers’ representatives, added important insights on the rainfall-yield relationship and were not just cumulative measures of rainfall but included specific weights for different plant growth phases and a “capping” procedure in order to take into account the fact that water in excess of storage capacity is lost and does not contribute to plant growth. This process allowed the indexes developed to reach correlation values of over 90 percent (Stoppa and Hess 2003) and to be greatly appreciated by potential end users.

 

Constraints

 

Despite the wide consensus gained by the proposed rainfall index contracts among government officials, insurers and producers, the implementation of the foreseen pilot programs in Morocco did not take place.

 

The main reason for the failure of the implementation process was the fact that rainfall precipitation in the selected areas showed a downward trend. Consequently, the reinsurance company involved in the deal made the cost of the insurance prohibitive for producers. The experience developed with the feasibility study and the implementation project for Morocco generated expertise that led to the realization of other WB-facilitated deals (for example, India) and of other independent programs (for example, Colombia).

 

INDIA: PRIVATE SECTOR-LED ALTERNATIVE AGRICULTURAL RISK MARKET DEVELOPMENT

 

Country context and risk profile

 

In 1991 a household survey addressing rural access to finance in India revealed that barely one-sixth of rural households had loans from formal rural finance institutions and that only 35-37 percent of the actual credit needs of the rural poor was being met through these formal channels (Hess 2003). A survey based on the Economic Census of 1998, (Hess 2003) shows that Indian formal financial intermediaries reportedly met only 2.5 percent of the credit needs of the unorganized sector through commercial lending programs.

 

Current response

 

Farmers respond to the lack of formal financial services by turning to moneylenders; reducing inputs in farming; overcapitalizing and internalizing risk; and/or by over-diversifying their activities which leads to sub-optimal asset allocation. Smallholders cannot risk investing in fixed capital or concentrating on the most profitable activities and crops, because they cannot leverage the start-up capital and they face catastrophic risks, such as drought, that could wipe out their livelihoods at any point in time. The challenge for banks is to innovate a low-cost way of reaching farmers and helping them better manage risk.

 

Proposed agricultural risk management structure

 

An initial study explored the feasibility of weather insurance for Indian farmers to determine if it would be possible to extend the reach of financial services to the rural sector by reducing the exposure to weather risk (Hess 2003). The study identified several potential project partners. In response to this study, CRMG, in collaboration with the Hyderabad-based microfinance institution, BASIX, and Mumbai-based insurance company, ICICI Lombard, a subsidiary of ICICI Bank, initiated a project to launch a small weather insurance pilot program for groundnut and castor farmers in the Andhra Pradesh district of Mahahbubnagar, the first weather insurance initiative ever to be launched in India.

 

The insurance contracts, protecting farmers from drought during the groundnut growing season, were designed by ICICI Lombard with technical support from CRMG and in consultation with BASIX. The products were marketed and sold by Krishna Bhima Samruddhi Local Area Bank (KBS LAB)34 extension officers to the four villages through workshops and meetings with the BASIX borrowers. In total, 230 farmers bought the insurance for khariff (monsoon season, June-September) 2003: 154 groundnut farmers and 76 castor farmers; most fell into the small farmer category, with less than 2.5 acres of landholding. The entire portfolio of weather insurance contracts sold by BASIX was insured by ICICI Lombard, with reinsurance from one of the leading international reinsurance companies.

 

ICICI Lombard was also involved in another project in khariff 2003 in Aligarh, Uttar Pradesh, where 1,500 soya farmers bought protection against excessive rainfall. ICICI Lombard filed all the necessary forms and terms of insurance with the Indian insurance regulator, registering their products before the programs were launched.

 

A second pilot program was launched in khariff 2004 and introduced significant changes to the 2003 design following farmer feedback from the pilot program, with technical assistance from CRMG. The program was extended to four new weather station locations, in two additional districts in Andhra Pradesh: Khammam and Anantapur. The weather insurance contracts were offered to both BASIX borrowers and nonborrowers and marketed and sold through KBS LAB in the Khammam and Mahahbubnagar districts and Bhartiya Samruddhi Finance Ltd. (BSFL)35 in the Anantapur district through village meetings, farmer workshops, and feedback sessions in the month leading up to the groundnut and castor growing season. New contracts were also offered for cotton farmers in the Khammam district and an excess rainfall product for harvest was offered to all castor and groundnut farmers. In total, over 400 farmers bought insurance through BASIX in 2004, and a further 320 groundnut farmers, members of a the Velugu self-help group organization in the Anantapur district, bought insurance directly from ICICI Lombard. Several farmers were repeat customers from the 2003 pilot. In contrast to 2003, ICICI Lombard did not seek reinsurance for the BASIX farmer/weather insurance portfolio in 2004.

 

In 2004, a number of other transactions also took place within the Indian private sector in response to the 2003 pilot program initiated by CRMG. In 2004, BASIX themselves bought a crop lending portfolio insurance policy based on weather indexes. For the first time, BASIX used this protection to cover their own risk and passed neither the cost nor the benefits to their farmers. The protection allowed BASIX to keep lending to drought-prone areas by mitigating default risk through the insurance policy claims in extreme drought years. BASIX bought a policy to cover three business locations, which was insured by ICICI Lombard, with structuring support from CRMG, and then reinsured into the international weather market.

 

During 2004, not only did BASIX expand their weather insurance program, a number of other institutions, including the originator ICICI Lombard, began expanding the market for weather insurance in India. IFFCOTokio, a joint venture insurance company, launched weather insurance contracts similar to the 2003 contracts in 2004, selling over 3000 policies to farmers throughout India. In conjunction with ICICI Lombard, the Government of Rajasthan launched a weather insurance program for orange farmers, insuring 783 orange farmers from insufficient rainfall in khariff 2004, and 1036 coriander farmers in rabi (October-March season) 2004. The National Agricultural Insurance Company (NAIC), responsible for the government-sponsored area-yield indexed crop insurance scheme, also launched a pilot weather insurance scheme for 20 districts throughout the country in 2004 reaching nearly 13,000 farmers — the scheme was even mentioned in the government of the Indian budget for the financial year 2004-2005. Therefore it is estimated that nearly 20,000 farmers bought weather insurance throughout India in 2004.

 

In 2005, BASIX/ICICI Lombard further improved the weather insurance product and automated underwriting and claims settlements. Thus, BASIX will sell area-specific weather insurance products in all of its 50 branches in 7 Indian states, targeting 10,000 farmers. In addition, ICICI Lombard is scaling up its agricultural weather insurance sales and is expanding into other sectors, while NAIC and IFCCO Tokio are stepping up their efforts to sell weather insurance products and developing better products for farmers.

 

An important element of the new pilot programs will be monitoring. Ultimately it will be important to learn not only if farmers are buying these products, but how it is changing their behavior and the lending behavior of local financial institutions. Box 6.1 describes the monitoring that is beginning for the India weather insurance products.

 

 

UKRAINE EXPERIENCE

 

Country context and risk profile

 

Rural financial institutions in Ukraine increasingly use future harvests as collateral since farm equipment is generally antiquated and of limited value. These lenders also tend to require harvest insurance to hedge against crop losses.36 The major banks active in agricultural lending, such as Aval (with a total of 4600 loans and 30 percent market share), do not lend on the basis of uninsured collateral, so to obtain credit, a farmer must have a proper insurance policy written by a preapproved insurer. To provide for the lending insurance needs of farmers, most banks set up their own insurance companies. Most farmers do not yet understand the particular nature of weather index insurance, but are familiar with weather risk and would like to have protection against natural, multiple perils.

 

Crop risk is diverse throughout Ukraine. Crop-yield data for five major crops (maize, sunflowers, sugar beets, wheat, and barley) in all 25 oblasts in the 1970-2001 period show there is a substantial geographic spread of the agricultural values concentrated in central and southern Ukraine. The correlation of crop yields between eastern Ukraine and the southern region near Odessa is nearly zero, facilitating risk pooling and in-country retention of a large share of natural risks.

 

Current response

 

In this market, the types of insurance policies currently offered are input cost insurance, generally linked to agricultural credit collateral requirements and limited to very low insured sums, and harvest insurance, covering hail, storm, excessive precipitation, frost, and fire risk. Drought is offered by only a few companies, but in general is not covered. Two crop insurance pools were founded in 2003 as part of attempts to provide more secure crop insurance to Ukrainian farmers. Five and sixteen insurance companies, respectively, agreed to pool their agricultural risks to improve their risk-bearing capacity and to obtain access to international reinsurance markets. Nevertheless, crop insurance policy sales were very limited (around 80 for both pools). Market participants cited the following reasons for the low uptake: inability to pay for the policy, unclear loss adjustment and underwriting procedures, mistrust of insurance companies, and insufficient information available to farmers. Moreover, by providing ad hoc disaster assistance to farmers in 2003 and 2004, the government of Ukraine (GoU) lowered incentives for farmers to pay for commercial insurance premiums. According to recent market information, by the end of 2004, the biggest agricultural insurance pool shrunk to six companies.

 

Policy objectives

 

The GoU has experimented with compulsory crop insurance and is now establishing a crop insurance subsidization scheme. The regulator has approved weather index insurance as an insurance product and a few weather insurance policies were sold to farmers in the first pilot sales season of 2005. A feasibility study by CRMG presents a risk management framework and considers several options for government intervention in the sector. An investment phase would consist of the acquisition and installation of automated weather stations, including the analysis of the density of the network required for the weather exposure of Ukraine and the design of an adequate maintenance program to ensure the quality of observations across time.

 

In addition, the GoU could consider a Backstop Facility for Weather Risk Insurance Retention. Ukrainian insurance companies would need international reinsurance for insuring against systemic risks. A risk pool “facility” in Ukraine would allow for the underwriting of agricultural reinsurance based on pre-established guidelines to retain as much risk inside the country as possible. This pool would then reinsure itself through a GoU fund. Extreme or catastrophic risk would be reinsured on the international reinsurance market based on transparent and competitive premium ratemaking principles; that is, once the pool and the GoU fund are depleted, international reinsurers would pay the remaining claims. Through the aggregation and layering of risk, reinsurers would be interested in reinsuring risk in Ukraine and forced to price the risk competitively. Individual insurance companies sometimes face insurmountable difficulties even accessing international reinsurance markets, let alone obtaining competitive prices. The combination of introducing a transparent index insurance product and an efficient and well-regulated risk pool can overcome this market failure. Risk layers representing relatively frequent (but mild) adverse events would be insured by the GoU risk fund. Intermediate risk layers (for example, 1-in-20–year events to 1-in-100– year events) could be transferred to the GoU Backstop Facility. The catastrophic risk layer (the 1-in-100– year event) could be transferred to international reinsurance markets.

 

ETHIOPIA: ETHIOPIAN INSURANCE CORPORATION AND DONOR-LED EX ANTE DISASTER RISK MANAGEMENT

 

Country context and risk profile

 

Ethiopia is one of the poorest and least developed countries in the world, ranking 169th of 175 countries in the Human Development Index. More than 85 percent of the population make their living in the agricultural sector which accounts for 39 percent of Ethiopia’s GDP (2002/2003) and 78 percent of foreign earnings. In Ethiopia, agriculture is predominantly rain fed and more than 95 percent of its output comes from subsistence and smallholder farmers. The staple diet for the majority of Ethiopians is coarse grains including maize, teff (a cereal grain), and sorghum. Production of coarse grains is valued at around US$380 million and cereals at US$585 million.

 

At the household level, adverse weather patterns, primarily lack of rain, are detrimental to yields and outputs and result in significant income losses and negative impacts on the livelihoods of farmers. Ethiopia faces highly variable rainfall and suffers from both national and regional droughts that can have extreme impacts on farmers who utilize traditional agricultural practices, using little irrigation, and rely on the country’s 35 million head of livestock. This rainfall variability, in addition to limiting the ability and motivation of farmers to invest in agricultural technology and yield-increasing assets, reduces overall production, which can decrease both consumption and income of households. At the national level, average grain production in the country is 8.9 million metric tons (MT) and is prone to recurrent drought.

 

The Ethiopian ministry of agriculture has indicated that the level of production is too low to feed the whole population even in good rainfall years.

 

Current response

 

With 10 percent of the population of 72 million requiring food aid assistance each year, food insecurity is a chronic issue. Emergency responses have been frequent if not constant, accounting for an annual average of 870,000 MT of food aid between 1994 and 2003. In 2003, a record 13 million Ethiopians required emergency assistance as a result of drought and the corresponding failed harvest in 2002. These emergency responses have saved millions of lives in the short term, but destitution has worsened, people’s assets have eroded, and vulnerability has increased. The uninsured loss of income and assets caused by natural disasters, primarily droughts, in developing countries such as Ethiopia, threatens the lives and livelihoods of vulnerable populations. Insurance is a critical requirement for development as uninsured losses lock entire populations in vicious cycles of deepening destitution. It is estimated that in sub-Saharan Africa, approximately 120 million people are at risk to natural disasters and for these populations, humanitarian aid provides the only insurance that protects their lives and livelihoods. But humanitarian aid is often too unreliable, unpredictable, and often times too untimely to provide an effective insurance function.

 

To partly address this issue, in 2003 the government of Ethiopia (GoE), donors, United Nations agencies, and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs), launched the New Coalition for Food Security, whose goal is to achieve food security for the population in Ethiopia who have been categorized as “chronically foodinsecure” and significantly improve food security for the additional 10 million people who are vulnerable in the next five years. To achieve these goals, the organizations are working through the government to introduce a productive safety net for 5 to 6 million people starting in January 2005. The safety net is not an emergency activity but an attempt to change the vulnerability and risk profile of the chronically food insecure. From January 2005, responses to chronic and emergency food shortages will be addressed by different channels: the former, essentially a development activity, will be addressed through the productive safety net program coordinated by the Food Security Coordination Bureau and the latter, a response mechanism to unpredictable humanitarian needs, will be tackled through the Disaster Prevention and Preparedness Commission (DPPC). Accordingly, those households that are not covered by the safety net program, but are still considered in need of government relief assistance, will fall under the emergency program through early warning and annual needs assessments.

 

Proposed agricultural risk management structures

 

In order to address the current situation in Ethiopia, two agricultural risk management structures are currently being considered, one at the farmer, micro-level and the other at the government, macro-level.

 

Micro-Level —Weather Insurance: The state-owned Ethiopia Insurance Corporation (EIC) plans to launch a small pilot weather insurance program for wheat farmers in southern Ethiopia in the wereda (district) of Assassa, Arsi Zone. The EIC has previously experimented with agricultural insurance for farmers but with little success. They are keen to explore new potential products to address the risks of larger, commercial farmers in the country. The pilot program is due to start in June 2005 and the EIC is receiving technical support from CRMG for the pilot. Part of the work includes the demand assessment and participatory design of the contracts with farmers in Assassa.

 

Macro-level — Ex Ante Funding of Emergency Relief Operations: The World Bank and the United Nations World Food Program (WFP) are investigating the feasibility of index-based weather insurance as a reliable, timely, and cost-effective way of funding emergency operations in Ethiopia. Specifically, the aim is to address the more extreme emergency situations, for example, as mechanisms to cope and mobilize small or localized emergency operations already established within the system, with the availability of the GoE strategic grain and cash reserve. Hence the aim is to target vulnerable populations who are not food insecure and are not included in the country’s new safety net program but are “at risk” to income and asset losses and consumption shocks resulting from the more severe natural disasters. It is estimated that at least a further 35 percent of the population, above those estimated as chronically food insecure and covered by the safety net, is at risk from hunger in the event of an extreme drought such as in 1984. For example a traditional food aid response to a catastrophic drought in today’s prices would be estimated to cost about US$1.6 billion, for all beneficiaries, chronic and nonchronic. Instead of the traditional funding approaches that rely on protracted appeals to international donors following a drought, the insurance approach focuses on transferring this risk to the reinsurance and capital markets. Such a mechanism will ensure predictable and timely availability of funds for the DPPC to launch emergency relief operations and appropriate interventions in the event of a well-defined rainfall deficit at harvest time. Some of the benefits of this type of insurance-based emergency funding include objective payouts, timely delivery, and funding in cash. In the case of Ethiopia, the insurance approach would allow intervention four months earlier than the traditional appeals-based system.

 

Policy objectives

 

Both proposed agricultural risk management structures are in line with the GoE current poverty reduction strategy, which focuses on 1) agricultural-led, rural-based growth, recognizing the importance of improving the environment for exports, private-sector growth, and rural finance; and linked to this, 2) food security. Clearly the micro-level weather insurance initiatives are complementary to the government’s primary focus on agricultural development.

The poverty reduction strategy is characterized by strong country ownership and focuses on a broad-based participatory process. In particular the GoE favors a gradual shift from food assistance, assistance in-kind, towards financial assistance that could be destined for the purchase of food from the domestic market

.

The New Coalition for Food Security is a testament to the government’s ambitious poverty reduction strategy: the main features of the safety net are multi-annual funding, transition towards cash-based programming, scaled-up public/community works, linkages with broader food-security programs, harmonized budgeting, and monitoring and evaluation. The Food Security Coordination Bureau has been created, under the Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development, to coordinate all food-security programming, including the safety net. Targeting the nonchronically hungry but food-insecure or vulnerable populations, an index-based weather insurance approach for Ethiopia that aims to provide contingency cash funding for responses to severe and catastrophic drought is clearly in line with the government’s strategy and complementary to the safety net initiative.

 

If the World Bank-WFP feasibility study indicates this is an appropriate approach for Ethiopia and the WFP, the aim is to pilot the concept and design an insurance contract for the WFP, transferring the risk to the international reinsurance markets for the 2006 growing season. In effect, in the pilot stage of the initiative, the WFP will be the counterparty to any commercial transaction with the international reinsurance markets and it is expected that donors will pay for the premium associated with this risk transfer. However, the ultimate aim of the initiative ideally would be for the GoE to take responsibility for this risk management program as part of their overall and long-term poverty reduction strategy.

 

Constraints

 

There are two major constraints that in the short term can limit the proposed risk management frameworks:

 

1. The first constraint comprises the weather-observing network and the weather data in Ethiopia.

The National Meteorological Services Agency (NMSA) is responsible for a network of over 500 weather stations and rain gauges throughout Ethiopia. However, not all of the weather stations have the reporting capabilities or the historical data of the quality sufficient to transfer risk to the international markets or even to perform an actuarial analysis of the weather risks involved.

 

Furthermore, given the large size and challenging topography of the country, the spatial distribution of the network is inadequate to protect the entire country from weather risk. These issues will hamper both micro- and macro-level efforts. On the micro-level, initially, only farmers who live near good weather stations will benefit from the availability of weather insurance. Furthermore, the EIC may find it difficult to secure reinsurance for this risk until the quality and security of the NMSA network improves. On the macro-level scale, the weather protection can only be designed using weather stations that adhere to the strict quality requirements of the international weather market. This will naturally limit the scope of the project in the first years.

 

2. The second constraint, more relevant for the macro-level weather-risk transfer, comprises fiscal constraints; namely, the ability of the government of Ethiopia to eventually take over the ex ante funding of the emergency relief operations program and take responsibility for the premium payments necessary to have this funding mechanism in place.

 

Products and risk transfer structure

 

Both micro- and macro-level proposals are focused on index-based weather risk management solutions.

 

Micro-level: At the micro-level, the EIC will market and sell weather insurance contracts to kebeles (small groups of farmers) and/or farming cooperatives to protect their farmer members from the financial costs associated with crop failure as a result of adverse weather. The products will be similar in concept to the products offered to farmers in India, but it will be sold at the group rather than individual level in line with farmer preferences identified during discussions and focus groups in Assassa. The EIC will then seek international reinsurance for their portfolio of weather risk.

 

Macro-level: At the macro-level, lack of rainfall is the dominant, immediate cause of emergency relief operations in Ethiopia. It is therefore an appropriate proxy for representing economic loss due to drought, and also a simple, objective basis for index insurance. The appropriate index must be based on a weighted average, or “basket,” of as many stations as possible to capture the macro-level nature of the risk the GoE faces. The government may be able to cope with small, localized droughts by transporting food supplies from other regions of the country and by sourcing government budget reserves. Retaining such risks will most probably be a more cost-effective solution than seeking insurance, and Ethiopia should be able to take advantage of any natural diversification of the country to reduce its insurance costs. However, in situations where drought affects several regions, is national, or when there is a severe regional drought, this reallocation of resources may not be manageable for the government, and it would be appropriate to utilize the basket-based insurance product to fund the expected emergency relief operations in a predictable and timely manner if such an event occurs. The basket approach also reduces the risk of reliance on one weather station and also the associated issues of moral hazard and basis risk. On this note, including more stations in the basket not only gives better national coverage and hence representation of the index, but also increases the placement potential of the structure in the international reinsurance markets.

 

In the pilot stage of the program, the WFP will be the counterparty to any commercial transaction with the international reinsurance markets and it is expected that donors will pay for the premium associated with this risk transfer. However, in the event of an extreme and catastrophic drought, any payment triggered by the insurance would be made available to the GoE DPPC. This would allow the provision of resources early to the GoE and thus the beneficiaries to ensure appropriate consumption smoothing and to avoid distressed sale of assets, which is vital if the intervention is to play an effective and protective role. With the availability of cash, the intervention can also be used to fund activities, other than food aid, that are already established in other parts of the country such as: cash-transfers, food-for-work, or cash-for-work schemes. Ultimately the long-term objective would be for the GoE to go directly to the market and take responsibility of this program, rather than through the intermediary WFP.

 

PERU: GOVERNMENT-LED SYSTEMIC APPROACH TO AGRICULTURAL RISK MANAGEMENT

 

Country context and risk profile

 

Peru is currently negotiating a Free Trade Agreement with the United States. One of the most vulnerable sectors to the opening of the economy is the agriculture sector because of its lack of competitiveness. In this context, the Ministry of Agriculture (MA) is preparing a multidimensional strategy that involves extension services to farmers and the engineering of innovative financial schemes, with the participation of the private sector to facilitate access to better technology and new markets. Due to farmers’ lack of bankable collateral, the MA intends to facilitate the emergence of a sustainable private agriculture insurance market

 

Current response

 

There have been two major efforts in the last decade to introduce agriculture insurance in Peru with disastrous results. The lack of technical knowledge and exposure to catastrophic events like El Niño generated big losses in the industry. From the consumers’ perspective, the previous schemes were not transparent and the lack of education translated into dissatisfaction about the scope and use of this financial instrument. Currently, crop insurance or similar instruments are not available to farmers.

 

Proposed agricultural risk management structure

 

The government of Peru (GoP) created a special commission in 2003 to draft a strategic plan for the implementation of an agriculture insurance scheme in Peru. The treasury ministry, agriculture department, insurance regulator, private and development bank representatives, farm unions, and insurance representatives participated in the discussions and recommendations for the strategic work plan. A specific body designed for that purpose is the Technical Committee for the Development of Agriculture Insurance (TCDAI), which was created by ministerial resolution in September, 2004, and is housed in the agriculture ministry. The TCDAI is currently working on several technical studies related to the design and implementation of agriculture insurance in Peru.

 

Policy objectives

 

The main objectives of the GoP are to 1) maintain prudent fiscal, monetary, and exchange rate policies, essential to attract investment and promote continued growth; and 2) complement growth with direct interventions to address inequality and poverty, focusing on excluded groups: indigenous people; Afro-Peruvians; and at-risk groups — youth and single mothers (Peru, 2004-6).

 

Constraints

 

In addition to fiscal constraints, Peru’s agricultural sector is divided between powerful export-oriented, high-value agricultural producers concentrated in 12 valleys along the coast, and the sierra- (highlands), and selva-based (jungle) smallholder agricultural producers.

 

Products

 

The technical committee, assisted by CRMG, proposes the following work plan:

 

Design of prototype index contracts: The feasibility of these types of contracts is tested for several crops located in the three main areas of Peru (coastal, sierra, and selva). The contract design requires weather data from the Peruvian weather service (SENAMHI). This is a priority for the work plan.

 

Demand assessment: This activity will aim at gauging the demand for weather insurance by type of producer and will include participatory design sessions that will address questions such as what types of contracts to develop and for what periods. This activity will include the training of potential end users (farmers) regarding index insurance basics (for example, types of indemnities, how are they calculated, how the contracts are settled, how the premiums are calculated).

 

Delivery model design: Based on a mapping of rural financial intermediation in Peru, this activity will evaluate segmented delivery models that would be used for real distribution channels to reach farmers with small- and medium-sized farms with viable production potential. Prototype contracts by institution and client segment will be used to work with potential intermediaries for contract designs.

 

Regulatory review: The purpose is to develop a strategic work plan with the insurance regulator to prepare the necessary technical documentation for the index insurance product to be approved under the guidelines of property insurance.

 

The TCDAI has defined the following crops and areas of interest for the feasibility study:

 

1. Rice — San Martín

2. Mango — Piura

3. Yellow maize — Lima

4. Potato — Huanuco

5. Coffee — Cuzco

6. Cotton (Tangis) — Ica

7. Cotton (Pima) — Piura

8. Asparagus — Lima

 

Risk-transfer structure

 

The GoP seeks to enhance risk-taking capacity in the country generally by facilitating special risk transfer arrangements with insurance companies in Peru — particularly those that wish to launch agricultural insurance. Specifically, the GoP wishes by set up a US$50 million fund that will take agricultural risk, managed by the leading second-tier bank (COFIDE). In addition, the technical committee plans to develop index-based products for insurers that can be directly transferred into international risk markets.

 

MONGOLIA: WORLD BANK CONTINGENT CREDIT FOR LIVESTOCK MORTALITY INDEX INSURANCE

 

Country context and risk profile

 

The economy of the Mongolian countryside is herder-based. Agriculture contributes nearly one-third of the national GDP and herding accounts for over 80 percent of agriculture. Animals provide sustenance, income, and wealth, protecting nearly half the residents of Mongolia. Shocks to the well-being of animals have devastating implications for the rural poor and for the overall Mongolian economy. Major shocks are common as Mongolia is a harsh climate and animals are herded with limited shelter. From 2000-2002, 11 million animals perished due to harsh winters (dzuds). The government of Mongolia has struggled with the obvious question of how to address this problem.

 

The Mongolian government requested specific assistance in coping with extreme livestock losses. Given the nature of highly correlated death rates for animals in Mongolia, an index-based livestock insurance (IBLI) product was proposed and in May 2005, the World Bank approved a loan to Mongolia to finance the Index-Based Livestock Insurance Project. This project will support a three-season pilot program in three states in Mongolia and includes a contingent debt facility to serve as a mechanism for protecting against extreme losses during the pilot. The major objective of the pilot program is to determine the viability of IBLI in Mongolia, including testing herders’ willingness to pay for an IBLI product. The index would pay indemnities based on adult mortality rates by species and by soum (province). By law, Mongolia performs a census of animals each year. Elaborate systems are in place to assure the quality of the data. The proposed pilot involves three distinct layers of risk: 1) self-retention by the herder; 2) a base insurance product (BIP) for mortality rates in a certain range; and 3) a disaster response product (DRP) for livestock losses beyond the layer covered by the insurer.

 

An index-based insurance program was recommended because of significant concerns about moral hazard, adverse selection, and extreme monitoring costs associated with any individual livestock insurance program in the vast open spaces of Mongolia. Weather index insurance was considered; however, it was determined that the weather events contributing to livestock deaths were too complex to develop this alternative. The project will support continued research to strengthen the mortality index by incorporating other indexes, for example the Normalized Difference Vegetation Index (NDVI), as a means of establishing a more secure index for paying losses.

 

While it is believed that the index-insurance product can be effectively underwritten, significant financial exposure for a nascent insurance market that has extremely limited access to global risk-shifting markets remains among the largest challenges. Given concerns about financing extreme losses, the pilot design involves a syndicate pooling arrangement for companies. Pooling risk among the insurance companies offers some opportunity to reduce the exposure for any individual insurer. In the short term, the government of Mongolia will offer a 105 percent stop loss on the pooled risk of the insurance companies.

 

Herder premiums go directly into a prepaid indemnity pool. Insurers must replace the reinsurance cost and the exposure above 100 percent for the prepaid indemnity pool.

 

In the syndicated pooling arrangement, participants share underwriting gains and losses based upon the share of herder premium they bring into the pool. Each insurer also pays reinsurance costs that are consistent with the book of business they bring into the pool. This gives the reinsurance pool the benefits of the pooling arrangement and provides the opportunity to build reserves for the overall activity. The reinsurance pool pays for the first layer of losses beyond the 105 percent stop loss. Once the reinsurance pool is exhausted, the government of Mongolia can call upon the contingent debt to pay for any remaining losses.

 

A major advantage of having a prepaid indemnity pool is that all other lines of the insurance business are protected from the extreme losses that can occur from writing an agricultural risk policy that is highly correlated. In addition, the long-term vision is for the syndicate to be well positioned to find risk-sharing partners in the global community quickly, as the pooling arrangement is both risky and profitable.

 

Reinsurers might be willing to provide capital and enter quota-share arrangements on that risk. To the extent that the risks within the pool are standardized, using the same measures and procedures, one can also envision this mechanism serving as a means to securitize the risk. Finally, the design also offers the opportunity to transition the system to the market once it is learned whether herders find the BIP an acceptable product and demonstrate a willingness to pay.

 

The first challenge to the risk transfer structure is the uncertainty of the livestock mortality index based on an annual government census of all animals in the country. Several systems are in place to monitor potential problems during the pilot, for example the movement of animals across soum borders. From the perspective of the reinsurer, even the government could have the incentive to tamper with the data if this data determines the level of reinsurance claims. The project seeks to establish systems to verify losses using third-party audits. A second challenge to this structure is the sustainability of the proposed pooling mechanism that determines reinsurance premiums for each participating insurer using advanced modeling procedures. Human capital within the country must be developed to perform these duties. Pooling mechanisms generally tend to fail because of collective action problems and high transaction cost. The challenge in Mongolia will be to move the pooling mechanism to a private-sector entity by the completion of the pilot; otherwise the system will likely be unsustainable if left to the government to maintain.

 

POTENTIAL ROLES FOR GOVERNMENTS AND THE WORLD BANK

 

Agricultural producers and other rural residents are often exposed to a variety of biological, geological, and climatic factors that can negatively affect household income and/or wealth. In addition, agricultural producers are often faced with tremendous variability in output and/or input prices. Given this environment, risk-averse individuals will often make investment decisions that reduce risk exposure but also reduce the potential for income gains and wealth accumulation. Thus, risk contributes to the “poverty trap” experienced by rural people in many developing countries.

 

For a variety of reasons (discussed in Chapter 2), markets for transferring these risks are typically either very limited or nonexistent. This “market failure” has stimulated a number of policy responses. Many developed countries have highly subsidized, farm-level agricultural insurance programs. Critics argue that, in addition to being very expensive, these programs stimulate rent-seeking activity, are highly inefficient, and may actually increase risk exposure by encouraging agricultural production in high-risk environments (Chapter 3). Regardless, given fiscal constraints in most developing countries, highly subsidized, farm-level agricultural insurance programs are not a realistic policy option.

 

Index-based insurance products have been proposed as an alternative risk-transfer mechanism for rural areas in developing countries. While not a panacea for all risk problems, index-based insurance products may prove to be valuable instruments for transferring the financial impacts of low-frequency, high-consequence systemic risks out of rural areas (Chapter 4). However, for a variety of reasons, government intervention may be required to generate socially optimal quantities of risk transfer. Governments need to carefully consider the extent and nature of any intervention in markets for index-based insurance products (Chapter 5). These efforts can be facilitated by World Bank policy advice, lending instruments, and monitoring and evaluation systems (see World Bank, 2004, 2005b). This chapter sets out policy and operational implications for governments and subsequently for the World Bank operational agenda.

 

GOVERNMENT ROLES

 

Risks in rural areas need to be managed at the macro-, meso-, and micro-levels. Governments need to 1) Understand the country’s rural risk profile; 2) Quantify the impact of this risk on the economy and revenues; 3) Design a rural risk management framework; and 4) Implement risk reduction and risk transfer.

 

Identify the risk profile for private and public assets and business flows

 

A natural risk assessment identifies the types of risks that affect major private and public assets and economic activities in rural areas.40 This assessment distinguishes between micro-level risk and macrolevel risk and considers both geographical and seasonal variations. Identification of risks at the microlevel is typically based on household surveys and also specific risk surveys. The objective is to understand the types of risks that affect households and the nature of those risks. At the macro-level the assessment would consider the aggregate economic effect of household risk with a particular focus on government budget exposure.

 

Quantify risk impacts at all levels

 

Once the major risks have been identified, governments need to quantify the potential impact of those risks. What is the magnitude of potential physical and indirect losses for different types of assets and economic activities? As represented in Figure 7.1, a variety of indirect business flow losses often compound the direct physical losses caused by natural hazards.

 

Design a rural risk management framework

 

Government intervention in risk transfer markets needs to be based on a careful analysis of market shortcomings and a clear statement of how government involvement will address those shortcomings (Chapter 5). A well-designed rural risk management framework clearly delineates public and private roles in the ex ante world of risk reduction and risk financing and also the ex post world of emergency response. This framework takes country-specific objectives and constraints into account instead of replicating developed country historical models (Chapter 3). The objective is to learn from these historical examples and then apply that understanding to country-specific efforts that incorporate new and innovative risk transfer instruments (Chapter 4). Private decision makers need to know where and how government would intervene at different risk levels in order to plan accordingly. Agricultural enterprises, for example, might intensify production if a credible and reliable insurance cover is in place.

 

Implement a risk management strategy

 

To be successful, a well-conceived risk management strategy must be supported by a credible government commitment that is sufficiently funded over the long term. While appropriate government roles will vary to reflect country-specific circumstances, one strategy might be government intermediation of index-based risk management products that are available in international capital and reinsurance markets and also the creation of infrastructure to support the development and implementation of new private risk management products.

 

WORLD BANK ROLES

 

The World Bank can engage in a number of activities that, in coordination with governments, may lead to increased risk-transfer opportunities for agricultural producers and other rural residents in developing countries. In general, these activities include educational efforts, incorporating risk management into holistic rural development strategies, investment lending operations designed to encourage the development of risk transfer markets, ex ante coordination of donor responses to natural disasters, and monitoring and evaluation of the performance of index insurance instruments.

 

Continue to build global knowledge of this new approach to agricultural risk management

 

The World Bank is uniquely placed to reach governments and decision makers on all continents. The World Bank, in general, and ARD, in particular, can facilitate technology transfer across continents. This economic and sector work of ARD will be disseminated outside the World Bank: in FY-06, CRMG is planning Global Distance Learning events that will have a component on agricultural risk management concepts and also two workshops in two different regions, possibly in connection with weather insurance pilot project launches; and inside the World Bank, mainly through “brown-bag” lunches and a workshop.

 

Risk management strategies should be explicitly incorporated into rural development strategy formulation and development policy lending programs

 

While the World Bank and the IMF have a long history of assisting governments in dismantling unsustainable mechanisms for managing price risk, often this is done in the absence of alternative risk management tools or a clear risk management agenda for deregulated markets. This gap has contributed to a breakdown in marketing arrangements and credit channels so that these efforts have sometimes not produced the projected results (Kherallah et al. 2002). The importance of addressing issues of collateral policies and institutional development as an integral part of reform is now widely understood, but in many circumstances, this is not a quick or easy task.

 

While the index-based risk management tools discussed here are not a cure-all, they can help credit institutions, producer organizations, and (in some cases) producers directly, to manage production risk, and by doing so they can help reconnect farmers to output and credit markets. In assisting policy makers in the design of reform programs, the World Bank should routinely consider how to facilitate the development of risk management instruments in the country, and should be prepared to support this process through policy advice, and in some cases, lending operations. Often, this may require reforms of collateral, macroeconomic, or regulatory policies. For example, risk management instruments using international markets cannot operate properly while exchange controls are in place. Often local regulations affecting insurance or financial markets will also need to be revised.

 

Because government or World Bank involvement in any risk management program may require trade-offs with other means of enhancing rural development and reducing vulnerability (for example, irrigation, infrastructure, etc.), the program should be embedded in an overall rural development strategy so these trade-offs can be carefully weighed. This will also allow for linkages with other rural development objectives (for example, rural finance).The overall rural development strategy should take a holistic approach to risk management, recognizing that diversification of income sources (remittances, off-farm employment) is often an important means of reducing rural vulnerability. In addition to formal risk management markets, the strategy should consider what reforms are needed to encourage income diversification and allow farmers full choices in a functioning market place. This may include, for example, market liberalization and privatization, investments in transportation, communication, and market infrastructure, legal rights that guarantee market access (especially for women and ethnic minorities), provision of market information, and measures to better integrate rural and nonrural labor markets (see Siegel 2005; Lanjouw and Feder 2001; Lloyd-Ellis 1999; and Mead and Liedholm 1998).

 

Attention should also be dedicated to safety nets designed to minimize the need to liquidate productive assets in times of emergency that can be scaled up quickly and efficiently (see Jorgensen and Van Domelen 1999; Jutting 1999; and Morduch 1999).

 

Investment lending operations can be used to encourage risk management

 

At the macro-level, a number of World Bank instruments (and those of other donors) exist or are being explored to cushion the fiscal and balance of payments adjustments required when countries are faced with shocks from natural disasters or international price movements of major commodity exports or imports. These include automatic mechanisms to adjust debt service — or even augment financing — in response to exogenous shocks. (For a full discussion, see World Bank, 2004, 2005b.)

At the meso-level, risk management tools can be used to improve the functioning of government social safety net programs, either at the central or more decentralized levels. For example, index-based insurance instruments could be used to provide ex ante contingent funding that would allow safety net programs to expand when they are most needed, without the delays and uncertainties caused by reliance on the budgeting process or on external aid. Likewise, use of index-based insurance by individual farmers, associations, processors, or rural finance institutions would reduce their degree of uncertainty and facilitate primary producers’ access to credit and input markets.

 

Although the primary World Bank tool now being used to support the development of risk management markets is AAA, investment lending projects may also be useful in some cases. Examples can be found in World Bank-facilitated price risk management efforts. In Turkey, for example, a Commodity Market Development Learning and Innovation Loan (LIL) had the objective of first supporting the development of physical commodity markets, which in the long term could evolve into a domestic platform for trading futures contracts. The project financed the upgrading of testing laboratories, warehouse facilities, and regional market infrastructure, and also technical assistance to enhance and harmonize grades and standards for some commodities, upgrade the warehouse receipts system, and improve the operations of the commodity market regulatory authority. While there is still no domestic futures trading, there has been progress toward the more limited objectives of establishing better linkages between producers and buyers and encouraging forward contracting for spot delivery, which is another means of reducing price risk. In addition, the project has facilitated more efficient price discovery: the prices for cotton and wheat determined on two exchanges which participated in the project are now used as the official record of domestic market prices for those two commodities.

 

Monitoring and evaluation of transactions

 

The work on index insurance in developing countries is still in an early stage and its development impact is not yet proven. A number of assumptions about the value of these instruments, their utility at the farm level, and their development impacts, need to be evaluated. CRMG has launched a first baseline study with DECRG (Research Department of the World Bank). Generally utility at the farm level can be gauged by the level of take-up of unsubsidized and unbundled products and particularly the level of repeat buying. Panel studies will reveal the actual impact of these products. Indicators are level of inputs used and diversification of farm activities, particularly the share of cash crops in the overall portfolio. Another important linkage will be to gauge if index insurance products improve access to credit or improve the terms of credit for small farmers in developing countries. Both the Indian and the Mongolian pilot project have very explicit monitoring and evaluation components that will attempt to gauge these activities.

As with any innovation, index insurance products for agricultural production risk will go through some significant changes in the next few years. It is likely that we will learn that they work under some circumstances and not under others. Mistakes will be made. Learning from those mistakes will take careful evaluation and adjustments. At this stage, the key value added from index insurance products appears to be the opportunity for structured ex ante financing of catastrophic risk that is tied to highly correlated losses resulting from weather risk in agriculture. Such risk cannot be pooled at the local level and the special structures introduced in this ESW give hope that they can be shifted into global markets.

 

 

25.10.2022

A Practical Method for Adjusting the Premium Rates in Crop-Hail Insurance with Short-Term Insurance Data

The frequency of hailstorms is generally low in small geographic areas. In other words, it may be very likely that hailstorm occurrences will vary between neighboring locations within a short period of time. Besides, a newly launched insurance scheme lacks the data. It is, therefore, difficult to sustain a sound insurance program under these circumstances, with premium rates based on meteorological data without a complimentary adjustment process.

18.10.2019

Malta - Vegetable production dropped 7% in 2018

Last year, Malta’s local vegetable produce dropped by 7% when compared to the previous year. The total vegetables produced in tonnes amounted to 58,178, down by 7% when compared to 2017. Their value too diminished as the total produce was valued at €30 million, down by 13% over the previous year. The most significant drop was in potatoes, down by 27% over the previous year. Tomatoes and onions were the only vegetables to have increased in volume, by 3% and 4% respectively but their value diminished by 9% and 24% respectively. The figures were published by the National Statistics Office on the event of World Food Day 2019, which will be celebrated on Wednesday. Cauliflower, cabbage and lettuce produce dropped by 10%, 3%, and 12% respectively. In the realm of local fruit, a drop of produce was registered here too apart from strawberries, which experienced a whopping increase of 58% over 2017. Total fruit produced in 2018 amounted to 13,057 tonnes, down by 1% when compared to 2017. The total produce was valued at €10 million, a 3% increase in value. Peaches produced were down by 35% and the 376 tonnes of peaches cultivated amounted to €0.5 million in value. Orange produce dropped by 10% and lemon produce dropped by 14%. There was no change in the amount of grapes produced and the 3,642 tonnes of grapes produced in 2018 were valued at €2.3 million. 70% of fruit and vegetables consumed in Malta is imported. The drop in local produce could be the result of deleterious or unsuitable weather patterns. Source - https://www.freshplaza.com

07.10.2019

USA - Greenhouse tomato production spans most states

While Florida and California accounted for 76 percent of U.S. production of field-grown tomatoes in 2016, greenhouse production and use of other protected-culture technologies help extend the growing season and make production feasible in a wider variety of geographic locations. Some greenhouse production is clustered in traditional field-grown-tomato-producing States like California. However, high concentrations of greenhouses are also located in Nebraska, Minnesota, New York, and other States that are not traditional market leaders. Among the benefits that greenhouse tomato producers can realize are greater market access both in the off-season and in northern retail produce markets, better product consistency, and improved yields. These benefits make greenhouse tomato production an increasingly attractive alternative to field production despite higher production costs. In addition to domestic production, a significant share of U.S. consumption of greenhouse tomatoes is satisfied by imports. In 2004, U.S., Mexican, and Canadian growers each contributed about 300 million pounds of greenhouse tomatoes annually to the U.S. fresh tomato market. Since then, Mexico’s share of the greenhouse tomato market has grown sharply, accounting for almost 84 percent (1.8 billion pounds) of the greenhouse volume coming into the U.S. market. Source - https://www.freshplaza.com

03.10.2019

World cherry production will decrease to 3.6 million tons

According to information from the USDA for the 2019-2020 season, world cherry production is expected to decrease slightly and amount to 3.6 million tons. This decline is due to the damages that the weather caused on cherry crops in the European Union. Even though Chile is expected to achieve a record export, world trade in cherries is expected to drop to 454,000 tons, based on lower shipments from Uzbekistan and the US. Turkey Turkey's production is expected to increase to 865,000. As a result of the strong export demand, producers continue to invest and improve their orchards, switching to high yield varieties and gradually expanding the surface for sweet cherries. More supplies are expected to increase exports to a record 78,000 tons, continuing its long upward trend. Chile Chile's production is forecast to increase from 30,000 tons to 231,000 as they have a larger area of mature trees. Between 2009/10 and 2018/19, the crop area has almost tripled, a trend that is expected to continue. The country is expected to export up to 205,000 tons in higher supplies. The percentage of exports destined for China has increased from 13 to almost 90% since 2009/10. China China's production is expected to increase by up to 24% and to amount to 420,000 tons, due to the recovery of the orchards that were damaged by frost last year. In addition, there are new crops that will go into production. Imports are expected to increase by 15,000 tons and to stand at 195,000 tons, as the increase in supplies from Chile will more than compensate for the lower shipments from the United States. Although higher tariffs are maintained for American cherries, the United States is expected to remain China's main supplier in the northern hemisphere. United States US production is expected to remain stable at 450,000 tons. Imports are expected to increase to 18,000 tons with more supplies available from Chile. Exports are forecast to decrease for the second consecutive year to 80,000 tons, as high retaliatory tariffs continue to suppress US shipments to China. If this happens, it will be the first time that US cherry exports experience a decrease in 2 consecutive years since 2002/03, when production suffered a fall of 44%. European Union EU production is projected to fall by more than 20%, remaining at 648,000 tons because of the hail that affected the early varieties in Italy, and the frost, low temperatures, and drought that caused a significant loss of fruit in Poland, the main producer. Lower supplies are expected to pressure exports to 15,000 tons and increase imports to 55,000 tons. Russia Russia's imports are expected to contract by 13,000 tons to 80,000 with lower supplies from Kazakhstan, Moldova, and Serbia. Source - https://www.freshplaza.com

09.08.2019

EU - 20% fewer apples and 14% fewer pears than last year

This year's European apple production is expected to come to 10,556,000 tons. That is 20% less than last year. It is also 8% less than the average over the past three years. The European pear harvest is expected to be 2,047,000 tons. This is 14% lower than last year and 9% less than the previous three seasons average. These figures are according to the World Apple and Pear Association, WAPA's top fruit prognoses. They presented their report at Prognosfruit this morning. Apple harvest per country Poland is Europe's apple-growing giant. This country is expected to process 44% fewer apples. The yield is expected to be 2,710,000 tons. Last year, this was still 4,810,000 tons. In Italy, yields are only three percent lower than last year. According to WAPA, this country will have an apple harvest of 2,195,000 tons. France takes third place. They will even have 12% more apples than last year to process - 1,652,000 tons. Pear harvest per country With 511,000 tons, Italy's pear harvest is much lower than last year. It has dropped by 30%. In terms of the average over the previous three seasons, this fruit's yield is 29% lower. In the Netherlands, the pear harvest is expected to be six percent lower, at 379,000 tons. This volume is still 3% more than the average over the last three years. Belgium has 10% fewer pears (331,000 tons) than last year. They are just ahead of Spain. With 311,000 tons, Spain who will harvest four percent more pears. Apple harvest per variety The Golden Delicious remains, by far, the largest apple variety in Europe. It is expected that 2,327,000 tons of these apples will be harvested this year. This is three percent less than last year. At 1,467,000 tons, Gala estimations are exactly the same as last year. The European Elstar harvest will also be roughly equivalent to last year. A volume of 355,000 tons of this variety is expected. Pear harvest per variety Looking at the different varieties, the European Conference is estimated to be 8% lower than last year. A volume of 910,000 tons is expected. The low Italian pear estimate will result in 34% fewer Abate Fetel pears (211,000 tons) being available. This is according to WAPA's estimate. This makes this variety smaller than the Williams BC (230.000 ton) in Europe. Source - https://www.freshplaza.com

30.01.2018

Spring frost losses and climate change not a contradiction in terms - Munich Re

Between 17 April and 10 May 2017, large parts of Europe were hit by a cold snap that brought a series of overnight frosts. As the budding process was already well advanced due to an exceptionally warm spring, losses reached historic levels – particularly for fruit and wine growers: economic losses are estimated at €3.3bn, with around €600m of this insured. In the second and third ten-day periods of April, and in some cases even over the first ten days of May 2017, western, central, southern and eastern Europe experienced a series of frosty nights, with catastrophic consequences in many places for fruit growing and viticulture. The worst-affected countries were Italy, France, Germany, Poland, Spain and Switzerland. Losses were so high because vegetation was already well advanced following an exceptionally warm spell of weather in March that continued into the early part of April. For example, the average date of apple flowering in 2017 for Germany as a whole was 20 April, seven days earlier than the average for the period 1992 to 2016. In many parts of Germany, including the Lake Constance fruit-growing region, it even began before 15 April. In the case of cherry trees – whose average flowering date in Germany in 2017 was 6 April – it was as much as twelve days earlier than the long-term average. The frost had a devastating impact because of the early start of the growing season in many parts of Europe. In the second half of April, it affected the sensitive blossoms, the initial fruiting stages and the first frost-susceptible shoots on vines. Meteorological conditions The weather conditions that accounted for the frosty nights are a typical feature of April, and also the reason for the month’s proverbial reputation for changeable weather. The corridor of fast-moving upper air flow, also known as the polar front, forms in such a way that it moves in over central Europe from northwesterly directions near Iceland. This north or northwest pattern frequently occurs if there is high air pressure over the eastern part of the North Atlantic, and lower air pressure over the Baltic and the northwest of Russia. Repeated low-pressure areas move along this corridor towards Europe, bringing moist and cold air masses behind their cold fronts from the areas of Greenland and Iceland. Occasionally, the high-pressure area can extend far over the continent in an easterly direction. The flow then brings dry, cold air to central Europe from high continental latitudes moving in a clockwise direction around the high. It was precisely this set of weather conditions with its higher probability of overnight frost that dominated from mid-April to the end of the month. There were frosts with temperatures falling below –5°C, in particular from 17 to 24 April (second and third ten-day periods of April), and even into the first ten-day period of May in eastern Europe. The map in Fig. 2 shows the areas that experienced night-time temperatures of –2°C and below in April/May. High losses in fruit and wine growing Frost damage to plants comes from intracellular ice formation. The cell walls collapse and the plant mass then dries out. The loss pattern is therefore similar to what is seen after a drought. Agricultural crops are at varying risk from frost in the different phases of growth. They are especially sensitive during flowering and shortly after budding, as was the case with fruit and vines in April 2017 due to the early onset of the growing season. That was why the losses were so exceptionally high in this instance. In Spain, the cold snap also affected cereals, which were already flowering by this date. Even risk experts were surprised at the geographic extent and scale of the losses (overall losses: €3.3bn, insured losses: approximately €600m). Overall losses were highest in Italy and France, with figures of approximately a billion euros recorded in each country. Two basic concepts for frost insurance As frost has always been considered a destructive natural peril for fruit and wine growing and horticulture, preventive measures are widespread. In horticulture, for example, plants are cultivated in greenhouses or under covers, while in fruit growing, frost-protection measures include the use of sprinkler irrigation as well as wind machines or helicopters to mix the air layers. Just how effective these methods prove to be will depend on meteorological conditions, which is precisely why risk transfer is so important in this sector. There are significant differences between one country and the next in terms of insurability and insurance solutions. But essentially there are two basic concepts available for frost insurance: indemnity insurance, where hail cover is extended to include frost or other perils yield guarantee insurance covering all natural perils In most countries, the government subsidises insurance premiums, which means that insurance penetration is higher. In Germany, where premiums are not subsidised and frost insurance density is low, individual federal states like Bavaria and Baden-Württemberg have committed to providing aid to farms that have suffered losses – including aid for insurable crops such as wine grapes and strawberries. Late frosts and climate change There are very clear indications that climate change is bringing forward both the start of the vegetation period and the date of the last spring frost. Whether the spring frost hazard increases or decreases with climate change depends on which of the two occurs earlier. There is thus a race between these two processes: if the vegetation period in any given region begins increasingly earlier compared with the date of the last spring frost, the hazard will increase over the long term. If the opposite is the case, the hazard diminishes. Because of the different climate zones in Europe, the race between these processes is likely to vary considerably. Whereas the east is more heavily influenced by the continental climate, regions close to the Atlantic coastline in the west enjoy a much milder spring. A study has shown that climate change is likely to significantly reduce the spring frost risk in viticulture in Luxembourg along the River Moselle1. The number of years with spring frost between 2021 and 2050 is expected to be 40% lower than in the period 1961 to 1990. By contrast, a study on fruit-growing regions in Germany2 concluded that all areas will see an increase in the number of days with spring frost, especially the Lake Constance region, where reduced yields are projected until the end of this century. At the same time, however, only a few preliminary studies have been carried out on this subject, so uncertainty prevails. Outlook The spring frost in 2017 illustrated the scale that such an event can assume, and just how high losses in fruit growing and viticulture can be. Because the period of vegetation is starting earlier and earlier in the year as a result of climate change, spring frost losses could increase in the future, assuming the last spring frost is not similarly early. It is reasonable to assume that these developments will be highly localised, depending on whether the climate is continental or maritime, and whether a location is at altitude or in a valley. Regional studies with projections based on climate models are still in short supply and at an early stage of research. However, one first important finding is that the projected decrease in days with spring frost does not in any way imply a reduction in the agricultural spring frost risk for a region. So spring frosts could well result in greater fluctuations in agricultural yields. In addition to preventive measures, such as the use of fleece covers at night, sprinkler irrigation and the deployment of wind machines, it will therefore be essential to supplement risk management in fruit growing and viticulture with crop insurance that covers all natural perils. Source - ttps://www.munichre.com/

17.05.2014

Russia Livestock Overview: Cattle, Swine, Sheep & Goats

Private plots generate 48 percent of cattle, 43 percent of swine and 54 percent of sheep and goats in Russia.  The Russian government recently approved a new program that will succeed the National Priority Project in agriculture (NPP) titled, “TheState Program for Development of Agriculture and Regulation of Food and Agricultural Markets in 2008-2012,” that encourages pork and beef production and attempts to address Russia’s declining cattle numbers.  This program includes import-substitution policies designed to stimulate domestic livestock production and to protect local producers. In the beginning of 2007, the economic environment for swine production was generally unfavorable.  The average production cost was RUR40-45/kilo of live weight, while the farm gate price was RUR40/kilo live weight.  Pork producers have been expressing concern for years about sales after implementation of the NPP as pork consumption is growing at a slower rate than pork production.  As a result, the pork sector has been lobbying the Russian government to regulate imports in spite of the meat TRQ agreement. From January-September 2007, 1.38 million metric tons (MMT) of red meat was imported.  A 12-year decline in beef production has resulted in limited beef availability in the Russian market leading to a spike in prices.  In response, the Russian government has been force to take steps to increase the availability of beef by lifting a meat ban on Poland and by looking to Latin America for higher volumes of product.  Feed stocks decreased during the first 11 months of 2007 compared to the previous year which will likely create even greater financial problems for livestock operations in 2008 as feed prices continue to skyrocket.  Grain prices increased rapidly in Russia through the middle of July 2007 before stabilizing at high levels as harvest progress reports were released. The Russian pig crop is expected to increase by 6 percent in 2008, while cattle herds are predicted to decrease by 3.5 percent.  Some meat market analysts predict that by 2012, as new and modernized pig farming complexes reach planned capacity, pork production could reach 3.5 MMT – up 75 percent from 2008 estimates. According to the Russian Statistics Agency (Rosstat), 1/3 of all Russian “large farms” are unprofitable.  Many of these are involved in livestock production.  Small, inefficient producers are uncompetitive and have already begun disappearing from the market. The Russian veterinary service continues to playa decisive role in meat import supply management. Source - http://www.cattlenetwork.com

27.11.2012

Statistics Canada : Farm income, 2011

Realized net income for Canadian farmers amounted to $5.7 billion in 2011, a 53.1% increase from 2010. This rise followed a 19.0% increase in 2010 and a 19.6% decline in 2009. Realized income is the difference between a farmer's cash receipts and operating expenses, minus depreciation, plus income in kind. Realized net income fell in four provinces: Newfoundland and Labrador, Nova Scotia, Manitoba and British Columbia. In each, increases in costs outpaced gains in receipts. Farm cash receipts Farm cash receipts, which include market receipts from crop and livestock sales as well as program payments, rose 11.9% to $49.8 billion in 2011. This was the first increase since 2008. Market receipts alone increased 12.0% to $46.3 billion. Crop receipts, which increased 15.8% to $25.9 billion, contributed the most to the increase. Sales from livestock products rose 7.5% to $20.3 billion, the largest annual increase since 2005. Stronger prices for grains and oilseeds played a major role in the increase in crop revenues. For example, canola receipts increased 37.3% in 2011 on the strength of a 27.3% gain in prices. Grains and oilseed prices started rising in the last half of 2010 as a result of limited global stocks and strong demand. Even though prices peaked in mid-2011, prices for the year, on average, remained well above 2010 levels. Crop receipts rose in every province except Manitoba and Newfoundland and Labrador. In Manitoba, difficult growing conditions reduced marketings of most grains and oilseeds. In Prince Edward Island and New Brunswick, increases in potato prices and marketings helped push crop receipts higher. It was also stronger prices that were behind the rise in livestock receipts. Hog receipts increased 15.5% to $3.9 billion on the strength of a 14.7% price increase. Cattle prices rose 19.5% in 2011, while receipts increased 1.1% because of a reduced supply of market animals. Hog, cattle and calf prices increased in 2010. The upward trend continued throughout most of 2011, primarily because of low North American inventories and high feed grain costs. Receipts for producers in the three supply-managed sectors-dairy, poultry and eggs-increased 7.9% as rising prices reflected higher costs for feed grain and other production inputs. A 14.9% rise in chicken receipts exceeded increases for eggs (+8.7%) and dairy products (+5.3%). Program payments increased 11.2% to $3.5 billion in 2011. Increases in Quebec provincial stabilization payments as well as crop insurance payments in Manitoba and Saskatchewan accounted for much of the rise. Farm expenses Farm operating expenses (after rebates) were up 8.4% to $38.3 billion in 2011, the second-largest percentage increase since 1981. This increase followed two consecutive years of modest declines. Higher prices for fertilizer, feed and machinery fuel contributed to the increase in operating expenses. According to the Farm Input Price Index, both fertilizer and machinery fuel prices were up by over 25% in 2011. At the same time, feed grain prices increased by more than 30%. When depreciation charges were included, total farm expenses increased 8.2% to $44.1 billion. Depreciation costs rose 6.9%. Total farm expenses advanced in every province in 2011. The largest percentage increases occurred in Saskatchewan (+12.3%), Quebec (+9.5%) and Alberta (+9.0%). Total net income Total net income reached $5.8 billion, a $3.3 billion gain. There were large increases in Saskatchewan (+$2.1 billion), Alberta (+$567 million) and Ontario (+$470 million), while Newfoundland and Labrador, New Brunswick and Manitoba saw declines. Total net income adjusts realized net income for changes in farmer-owned inventories of crops and livestock. It represents the return to owner's equity, unpaid labour, and management and risk. The total value of farm-owned inventories rose by $165 million in 2011. A strong increase in deferred grain payments together with the first increase in cattle inventories since 2004 contributed to the rise. Note to readersRealized net income can vary widely from farm to farm because of several factors, including commodities, prices, weather and economies of scale. This and other aggregate measures of farm income are calculated on a provincial basis employing the same concepts used in measuring the performance of the overall Canadian economy. They are a measure of farm business income, not farm household income. Financial data for 2011 collected at the individual farm business level using surveys and other administrative sources will soon be tabulated and made available. These data will help explain differences in performance of various types and sizes of farms. For details on farm cash receipts for the first three quarters of 2012, see today's "Farm cash receipts" release. As a result of the release of data from the 2011 Census of Agriculture on May 10, 2012, data on farm cash receipts, operating expenses, net income, capital value and other data contained in the Agriculture Economic Statistics series are being revised, where necessary. The complete set of revisions will be released in the November 26, 2013, edition of The Daily. Table 1 Net farm income 2009 2010r 2011p 2009 to 2010 2010 to 2011 millions of dollars % change + Total farm cash receipts including payments 44,599 44,466 49,772 -0.3 11.9 - Total operating expenses after rebates 36,052 35,315 38,276 -2.0 8.4 = Net cash income 8,547 9,151 11,496 7.1 25.6 + Income-in-kind 39 40 45 2.6 11.1 - Depreciation 5,471 5,483 5,864 0.2 6.9 = Realized net income 3,115 3,709 5,677 19.0 53.1 + Value of inventory change -281 -1,157 165 ... ... = Total net income 2,834 2,551 5,842 ... ... Table 2 Net farm income, by province Canada Newfoundland and Labrador Prince Edward Island Nova Scotia New Brunswick Quebec millions of dollars 2010r + Total farm cash receipts including payments 44,466 118 407 500 479 7,171 - Total operating expenses after rebates 35,315 106 367 422 406 5,472 = Net cash income 9,151 12 41 78 73 1,699 + Income-in-kind 40 0 0 1 1 10 - Depreciation 5,483 8 41 59 54 727 = Realized net income 3,709 4 0 19 20 983 + Value of inventory change -1,157 -0 18 0 9 13 = Total net income 2,551 4 18 19 29 996 2011p + Total farm cash receipts including payments 49,772 120 477 527 533 7,967 - Total operating expenses after rebates 38,276 114 391 448 424 6,018 = Net cash income 11,496 6 86 79 109 1,949 + Income-in-kind 45 0 0 1 1 11 - Depreciation 5,864 9 43 62 55 767 = Realized net income 5,677 -2 43 18 55 1,194 + Value of inventory change 165 -0 -12 2 -50 -24 = Total net income 5,842 -3 31 20 5 1,170 Source - http://www.4-traders.com/

istanbul escort şişli escort tbilisi escort şişli escort şişli escort maslak escort istanbul escort beşiktaş escort taksim escort izmir escort ümraniye escort mecidiyeköy escort şişli escort taksim escort ümraniye escort kartal escort şirinevler escort maltepe escort istanbul escort ümraniye escort kadıköy escort vip escort mersin escort istanbul escorts ataköy escort avcılar escort beylikdüzü escort okmeydanı escort şişli escort tuzla escort işitme cihazı sex shop sex shop sex shop sex shop sex shop sex shop sex shop sex shop